The Illogic in Fractional Reserve Banking
If there was one business venture the leftist and forgotten “Occupy”
movement was right to distrust, it was the banking industry. In the wake of the
2008 financial crisis and subsequent bailing out of the world’s financial
system by fascist states, taxpayers – especially the progressive types – were
correct to feel amiss. But rather than take a scrutinizing look into the
privilege afforded to the banking class, the outraged took to political action
in the callow hope of correcting a wrong.
Like any popular uprising, the goal was
quickly smothered in favor of further rent-seeking. Instead of aiming
consternation at the incestuous relationship between government and the
money-changers, occupiers wanted the quick-fix of redistribution. The cries of
“this is what democracy looks like” might as well have been “this is what
panhandling looks like.” Centralized banking went unquestioned. The nature of
fractional reserve practices was ignored – or likely not understood by the pea-brained philosophers.
Still, the radical levellers who set-up camp in Zuccotti Park were on to
something by asking why their precious public officials voted to shore up the
balance sheets of a disproportionately small member caste.
Banking is, to put it bluntly, a strange
and unique business. The industry is centuries-old, and the legality of its
operations has been questionable since inception. I am referring specifically
to the practice of bankers lending out claimed reserves – a contentious issue
among libertarian theorists. If the larger public were to become privy to this
business model, it may spark a troubling curiosity in the less-moneyed class.
But then again, this author never ceases to be amazed by the bounds of common
apathy.
In banking, certain legal doctrines have guided the trade since antiquity, including the nature of contracts. The violation of these distinct forms of lawful guarantees once carried the weight of justice. But no longer; as the deliberately obscuring practice of loaning out deposits meant to be available on-demand has created such instability in the banking system, the incessant teetering on the cliff of insolvency remains an ever viable threat to economic tranquility.
Libertarians – specifically those schooled
in the Austrian, causal-realist tradition of economics – are intellectually
miles ahead of the Occupy folks when it comes to the study of currency. And
while the students of Mises and Hayek are fervently opposed to any central bank
management, there remains a sharp divide on the ethics of fractional reserve
banking. In a recent missive in the Freeman, economist Malavika Nair questions the
Rothbardian ethic that finds the practice of banks creating credit out of thin
air fraudulent. The piece, which deconstructs the dean of the Austrian school’s
original argument, frames banking away from the supposed cut-and-dry thinking
model of anti-fractionalists.
Nair begins with a false choice by asking:
“Would fractional reserve banking exist in a world without a central bank? Put
another way: Is fractional reserve banking inherently fraudulent?” These
statements are not one in the same; they reference two separate conditions.
Absent central banking, unbacked credit expansion could still exist. Back in
mid-to-late 19th century America where the Federal Reserve was still a twinkle
in the centralizers’ eyes, fractional reserve banking and pyramiding credit
were common practice. The question at hand is whether such
business is based on a fraudulent understanding of the nature of goods.
Nair finds issue with the essence of
contracts and how they relate to the duty of those individuals entrusted with
safeguarding money. The contract – an
extension of humanity’s self-ownership and free will – has been a recognized
covenant enforceable by compulsion for as long as man first conceived of
himself as an autonomous being. It finds legitimacy in the human understanding
of bonds and keeping one’s word. The evolution of common law has dictated that any activity stipulated
in a compact cannot entail unlawful activity. To enforce an illegal activity
would thereby be a crime in itself – an ipso facto contradiction in reason.
The contract is key for banking
operations. Nair argues that bank functions, both deposit and lending, are
plainly justifiable; the discrepancy arises in the manner that customer funds
are utilized. Currently, bankers freely lend out money that is available on
command by both the borrower and depositor. In practice, this is the creation
of two goods from one ex nihilo. In a totally isolated instance where a bank
were to service only two patrons, the act of creating what Mises called
“fiduciary media” would appear as the very perversion of intuitive law it
embodies. It would simply come off as no more than a violation of the known
rules of the world.
Nair counters by asserting that a “claim
to money is not the same thing as the money itself.” This is a confusing
affirmation as antagonists to fractional reserve banking hardly make that
claim. The point of contention is that promissory notes for bank deposits
represent real money, though they may circulate as mediums of exchange and
fulfill the role of currency. Should two or more of these “I owe you”
certificates be created to represent one unit of bank reserves available
on-demand, there is a direct and unquestionable inconsistency. It is certainly
true, as Nair points out, that the fungible quality of money dictates it be
treated differently than non-substitutable goods. However, the fact that cash
is interchangeable does not dismiss its limited character.
If the principle of unbacked expansion of
credit were applied to other industries such as automobiles or condominiums,
titles to the same good could theoretically be multiplied, but not without
controversy. Having two titles for one car is not based on logic or a firm
understanding of universal law. You simply cannot create real, definite
material by declaration. Nair asserts that this is not true when it comes to
the market of money. In his words, the over-issuing of redeemable bank notes
“does not mean one thing is in two places at the same time” but that “two
different things are in two places at the same time.” This is only so much
sophistry, as the claims to bank reserves are still representative of real
goods. There may be multiple slips of paper representing one unit of
money-proper floating around in the economy, but that does not dismiss the
plain and true fact that there are more claims than what is available.
As economist Jesús Huerta de Soto
documents in his tour de force Money, Bank
Credit, and Economic Cycles, government has played a leading role in
fostering this banking fraud for centuries. The state is forever on the search
for more resources to carry out its bidding. Cooperation with the leading
money-lending institutions was an obvious route for subverting the moral means
to wealth creation. Since the days of classical Greece, it was well understood
that transactions of present goods fundamentally differed from those involving
future goods. In practical terms, deposits for safekeeping were of considerable
difference to those made for the strict purpose of lending out and garnering a
return. Bankers who misappropriated funds were often found guilty of fraud and
forced to pay restitution. In one recorded episode, ancient Grecian legal
scholar Isocrates lambasted Athenian banker Passio for reneging on a client’s
depository claim. After being entrusted to hold a select amount of money, the
sly banker loaned out a portion of the funds in the hopes of earning a profit.
When asked to make due on the deposit, the timid Passio pleaded to his accuser
to keep the transgression “a secret so it would not be discovered he had
committed fraud.”
The underlying chicanery behind fractional
reserve banking has existed since the days of Plato. Modern technology has not
negated the rationale used to discover and affirm natural law. Binary codes on
a computer screen do not create a new reality. The governing doctrines of
humanity are, in de Soto’s words, “unchanging and inherent in the logic of
human relationships.” While fractional reserve banking could exist in a free
market environment and regulate itself through vigorous competition, that
theoretical scenario does not prove the entire fulcrum of the business rests on
solid ground.
The truth remains, and will always remain,
that an organic product is not replicable through any kind of witch doctoring.
A thing is a thing is a thing. Any money substitute that represents a real
piece of fungible currency cannot pertain to that which is not in existence.
Such is the lawful understanding that goes back to the time preceding the
Hellenisitc period.
Malavika Nair offers an interesting
argument by trying to justify the practice of creating something out of
nothing; but it ultimately fails. The free lunch of artificial credit creation
is nothing more than slipping out of the baker’s shop without paying. It would
have served the Occupy crowd well to have recognized this shaky foundation upon
which the modern financial system rests. Perhaps their message of widespread
corruption would have been better received – at least more so than by creating shanty
towns and defecating on the street. Instead, we were gifted with a muddled and
confused political message made by an irate minority who hadn’t a clue of the
forces that govern their own lives.
No comments:
Post a Comment