Wall Street, Banks, and American Foreign Policy
Murray Rothbard’s
1984 analysis of modern American history as a great
power struggle between economic elites, between the House of Morgan and the Rockefeller
interests, culminates in the
following conclusion: “the financial power elite can sleep well at night regardless of
who wins in 1984.” By the time
you get there, the conclusion seems understatedindeed, for what we have here is
a sweeping and compressed history
of 20th century politics from a power elite
point of view. It represents a small and highly specialized sample of Rothbard’s vast historical
knowledge coming together with a
lifetime devoted to methodological individualism in the social sciences. It appeared
first in 1984, in the thick of
the Reagan years, in a small financial publication called World Market Perspective. It
was printed for a larger audience
by the Center for Libertarian Studies in
1995, and appears in 2005 online for the first time.
Theoreticians Left and Right are constantly
referring to abstract “forces” when
they examine and attempt to explain historical patterns. Applying the principle of methodological
individualism – which attributes
all human action to individual actors –
and the economic principles of the Austrian School, Rothbard formulated a trenchant
overview of the Americanelite and the history of the modern era.
Rothbard’s analysis flows, first, from the basic
principles of Austrian economics,
particularly the Misesian analysis of banking and
the origin of the business cycle. This issue is alsodiscussed and elaborated on
in one of his last books, The Case
Against the Fed (Mises Institute, 1995). Here, the author relates the history
of how the Federal Reserve System
came to be foisted on the unsuspecting American people by a high-powered alliance of
banking interests. Rothbard’s
economic analysis is clear, concise, and wide-ranging, covering the nature of money, the
genesis of government paper
money, the inherent instability (and essential fraudulence) of fractional reserve banking, and the
true causes of the business
cycle.
As Rothbard
explains in his economic writings, the key is in understanding that money is a
commodity, like any other, and
thus subject to the laws of the market. A government-granted monopoly in this, the very lifeblood
of the economic system, is a
recipe for inflation, a debased currency – and the creation of a permanent plutocracy
whose power is virtuallyunlimited.
In the
present essay, as in The Case Against the Fed, it is in the section on the history of
the movement to establish the
Federal Reserve System that the Rothbardian power elite analysis comes into full and
fascinating play. What is striking about
this piece is the plethora of details. Rothbard’s argument is so jam-packed with facts detailing
the social, economic, and
familial connections of the burgeoning Money Power,
that we need to step back and look at it in the light of Rothbardian theory, specifically
Rothbard’s theory of class
analysis.
Rothbard eagerly reclaimed the concept of class
analysis from the Marxists, who
expropriated it from the French theorists of
laissez-faire. Marx authored a plagiarized, distorted, and vulgarized version of the theory
based on the Ricardian labor
theory of value. Given this premise, he came up with a class analysis pitting workers
against owners.
One of
Rothbard’s many great contributions to the cause of liberty was to restore the original theory,
which pitted the people against
the State. In the Rothbardian theory of class struggle,the government,
including its clients and enforcers, exploits and
enslaves the productive classes through taxation, regulation, and perpetual war. Government is an
incubus, a parasite, incapable of
producing anything in its own right, and instead feeds off the vital energies and
productive ability of the producers.
This is
the first step of a fully-developed libertarian class analysis. Unfortunately, this is where
the thought processes of all too
many alleged libertarians come to a grinding halt.
It is enough, for them, to know the State is the Enemy, as if it were an irreducible primary.
As William
Pitt put it in 1770, “There is something behind the throne greater than the king
himself.” Blind to the real
forces at work on account of their methodological error, Left-libertarians are content to live
in a world of science fiction and
utopian schemes, in which they are no threat to
the powers that be, and are thus tolerated and at times even encouraged.
The Left-libertarian
failure to take the analytical process one
step further is, in many cases, a failure of nerve. For it is clear, given libertarian
theory and the economic insights
of the Austrian School, where the next step leads. No empirical evidence is necessary, at
this point (although that will
come later, and in spades); the truth can be deduced from pure theory, specifically the
Austrian theory of the nature of
money and banking, and the Misesian analysis of the origin of the business cycle.
This deduction
was brilliantly and colorfully made in the first issue of The Journal of Libertarian
Studies (Winter 1977), by two
students of Rothbard, Walter E. Grinder and John
Hagel III, in “Toward a Theory of State Capitalism: Ultimate
Decision-Making and Class
Structure.”
While a
pure free market would necessarily prevent the development of a banking monopoly, “however, the
market system does concentrate
entrepreneurial activity and decision-makingwithin the capital market because
of the considerable benefits which
are rendered by a certain degree of specialization.”
This “specialized
capital market, by the very nature of its integrative role within the market system, will
emerge as a strategic locus of
ultimate decision-making.” Given that some individuals will choose the political means over
the economic, some of these great
fortunes will utilize their tremendous resources to cartelize the market and insulate
themselves againstrisk. The temptation for bankers in particular to wield the power of the State to their
benefit is very great because it
permits banks to inflate their asset base systematically. The creation of assets made possible
by these measures to a great
extent frees the banking institutions from the constraints imposed by the passive form of
ultimate decision-making exercised
by their depositors. It thereby considerably strengthens the ultimate decision-making authority
held by banks vis–vis their
depositors. The inflationary trends resulting from the creation of assets tend to
increase the ratio of external financing
to internal financing in large corporations and,as a consequence, the ultimate
decision-making power of banking
institutions increase over the activities of industrial corporations.
The Austrian
insight focuses on the key role played by the central banks in generating the distortion of
market signals that leads to
periodic booms and busts, the dreaded business cycle which is always blamed on the
inherent contradictions of
unfettered capitalism.
But in
fact this capitalism is anything but unfettered. (Try starting your own private bank.) The
last thing American bankers want
is an unfettered banking system. Rothbard not only
traces the original market distortion that gives rise to the business cycle, but also
identifies the source (and chief
beneficiaries) of this distortion. It was Mises who pointed out that government
intervention in the economy invariably
leads to yet more intervention in order to “fix” the havoc wreaked – and there is a
certain logic in the fact that it
was the original culprits who decided to “fix”
the distortions and disruptions caused by their policies with further assaults on the market
mechanism. As Grinder and Hagel
put it:
In the U.S., this intervention initially
involved sporadic measures, both
at the federal and state level, which generated inflationary distortion in the
monetary supply and cyclicaldisruptions of economic activity. The disruptions
which accompanied the business
cycle were a major factor in the transformation
of the dominant ideology in the U.S. from a
general adherence to laissez-faire doctrines to an ideology of political capitalism which viewed
the state as a necessary instrument
for the rationalization and stabilization of an
inherently unstable economic order.
Capitalists as Enemies of Capitalism
This explains
the strange historical fact, recounted at length and in detail by Rothbard, that the
biggest capitalists have been the
deadliest enemies of true capitalism. For virtually
all of the alleged social “reforms” of the past fifty years were pushed not only by
“idealistic” Leftists,but by the very corporate combines caricatured as the
top-hatted, pot-bellied “economic
royalists” of Wall Street.
The neoconservative
Right depicts the battle against Big Government as a two-sided Manichean struggle
between the forces of light (that
is, of capitalism) and the remnants of largely discredited Leftist elites. But
Rothbard’s historical analysis reveals
a much richer, more complex pattern: instead of being two-sided, the struggle for
liberty pits at least three
sides, each against the other. For the capitalists, as John T. Flynn, Albert Jay Nock, and
Frank Chodorov all pointed out,
were never for capitalism. As Nock put it:
It is one of the few amusing things in
our rather stodgy world that
those who today are behaving most tremendously about collectivism and the Red menace are
the very ones who have cajoled,
bribed, flattered and bedeviled the State into taking each and every one of the
successive steps that lead straight
to collectivism. ["Impostor Terms," Atlantic Monthly, February 1936.]
The New
Deal economic policy was, as Rothbard demonstrated, prefigured by Herbert Hoover, champion
of big business, and foreshadowed
in the reforms of the Progressive era.As the revisionist economic historians,
such as Gabriel Kolko, have
shown, those who regulated the great industries in the name of progressive “reform”
were recruited from the very
cartels and trusts they were created to tame.
And of
course the monopolists didn’t mind being tamed, so long as their competitors were tamed (if
not eliminated). Every giant leap
forward of economic planning and centralization– central banking, the welfare
state, “civil rights,” and
affirmative action – was supported if not initiated by the biggest and most politically
powerful business interests in
the country. The House of Morgan, the Rockefellers, and the Kuhn-Loebs must take their place
alongside the First, Second, and
Third Internationals as the historic enemies of
liberty.
Giant multinational
corporations, and their economic satellites, in
alliance with governments and the big banks, are in the process of extending their influence
on a global scale: they dream of
a world central bank, global planning, and an
international welfare state, with American troops policing the world to guarantee their profit
margins.
After the
long battle to create a central bank in the U.S., the high priests of high finance finally
seized and consolidated control
of domestic economic policy. It only remained forthem to extend their dominance
internationally, and for this
purpose they created the Council on Foreign Relations, and, later, the Trilateral Commission.
These two
groups have been seized upon by the new populist Right as the virtual embodiments of the
Power Elite, and rightly so. It
is only by reading Rothbard, however, that this insight is placed in its proper historical
perspective. For the fact of the
matter is that, as Rothbard shows, the CFR/ Trilateralist
network is merely the latest incarnation of a
trend deeply rooted in modern American history. Long before the founding of the CFR or the
Trilateral Commission, there was
a power elite in this country; that elite will likely endure long after those organizations
are gone or transmuted into
something else. Rothbard’s unmasking of the historical and economic roots of this trend is
vital in understanding that this
is not a “conspiracy” centered in the CFR and the
Trilateralist groups, as such, but an ideological trend traditionally centered in the
Northeast, among the upper classes,
and deeply rooted in American history.
I put
the word “conspiracy” in quotes because it has become the favorite swearword of the
Respectable Right and the “extremist”-baiting
Left. If it is conspiracy-mongering to
believe that human beings engage in purposeful activity to achieve their economic, political,
and personal goals, then rational
men and women must necessarily plead guilty. The
alternative is to assert that human action is purposeless, random, and inexplicable. History, in
this view, is a series of
discontinuous accidents.
Yet it
would be inaccurate to call the Rothbardian world view a “conspiracy theory.” To say that the
House of Morgan was engaged in a
“conspiracy” to drag the U.S. into World War I,
when indeed it openly used every stratagem, every lever both economic and political, to
push us into “the war to end all
wars,” seems woefully inadequate. This was not
some secret cabal meeting in a soundproof corporate boardroom, but a “conspiracy” of ideas
openly and vociferously expressed.
(On this point, please note and underscore Rothbard’s analysis of the founding of The New
Republic as the literary flagship
of “the growing alliance for war and statism” between
the Morgan interests and liberal intellectuals – and isn’t it funny how some things
never change?)
A conspiracy
theory attributes virtually all social problems to a single monolithic agency. Radical
feminism, which attributes all
the evil in the world to the existence of men, is aclassic conspiracy theory;
the paranoid views of the ex-Communists in
the conservative movement, who were obsessed with destroying their ex-comrades, was another.
But the
complexity and subtlety of the Rothbardian analysis, backed up by the sheer mass of rich
historical detail, sets Rothbard
on an altogether different and higher plane. Here there is no single agency, no
omnipotent central committee that
issues directives, but a multiplicity of interest groups and factions whose goals are generally
congruent.
In this
milieu, there are familial, social, and economic connections, as well as ideological complicity, and
none is better than Rothbard at
ferreting out and unraveling these biographical details. Taken together, the author’s
small and studied brushstrokes
paint a portrait of a ruling class whose ruthlessness is surpassed only by its brazen
disloyalty to the nation.
It is
a portrait that remains unchanged, in its essentials, to this day. Wall Street,
Banks, and American Foreign Policy was
written and published in 1984,
during the Reagan years.
Reagan started
out by denouncing the power elite and specifically the CFR and the Trilateralists, but
wound up with that epitome of the
Establishment, Skull-&-Bonesman George Bush as his vice president and successor.
Bush is
a longtime CFR director, and Trilateralist; most of his major cabinet officers, including his
chairman of the joint chiefs,
Colin Powell, were CFR members. The Clinton administration is similarly afflicted, from the
President (CFR/Trilateral) on
down through Donna Shalala (CFRJ Trilateral) and George Stephanopoulos (CFR), with the CFR
honeycombed (as usual) throughout
the State Department. In addition to Secretary of State Warren Christopher, other CFR
members in the Clinton cabinet
include Laura Tyson, chairman of the Council of Economic advisors, Treasury Secretary
Robert Rubin; InteriorSecretary Bruce Babbitt, HUD honcho Henry Cisneros; and Alice Rivlin, 0MB director.
The other
side of the aisle is equally co-opted at the leadership level, as vividly dramatized by
Gingrich’s retreat before the
power and majesty of Henry Kissinger. One naturally expects cowardice from politicians,
but the indictment also includes
what passes for the intellectual leaders of the Republican free-market “revolution.”
There is
a certain mentality that, no matter how convincing the evidence, would never even consider
the argument put forward in Wall
Street, Banks, and American Foreign Policy. Thisattitude stems from a
particular kind of cowardice. It is a
fear, first of all, of not being listened to, a dread of consigning oneself to the role of
Cassandra, the ancient Greek
prophetess who was granted the power of foresight by the gods, with but a single
limitation: that none wouldever heed her warnings. It is far easier, and so
much more lucrative, to play the
role of court historian.
This is
a role the author of this scintillating pamphlet never could have played, even if he had tried.
For the truth (or, at least, the
search for it) is so much more interesting than
the official histories and the conventional wisdom of the moment. The sheer pleasure
Rothbard took in unearthing the
truth, in carrying out his vocation as a true scholar, is evident not only on every page of
the present work but throughout
his 28 books and thousands of articles and speeches.
Rothbard was not afraid of sharing Cassandra’s
fate because, in the first place,
truth is a value in its own right, and ought to
be upheld for its own sake. Second, the truth has a way of eventually getting out, in spite of
the most strenuous efforts to
suppress it.
No comments:
Post a Comment