The new “fatal” conceit
By Václav Klaus
We all have
our heroes, and Hayek was, for me, one of the greatest ones. It all started in
the 1960s. My country, then Czechoslovakia, experienced at the beginning of the
decade an unexpected and, for communist leaders, ideologically unexplainable
and indefensible economic recession — the first that had happened in a
centrally planned communist country in peacetime. It was something unheard of,
something unimaginable. Planning was supposed to guarantee permanent and
harmonious economic growth. That surprising and unpleasant experience led even
the most dogmatic communist politicians to think about a relatively
far-reaching economic reform and to start implementing it. As is well known
now, they tried to accomplish an impossible mission, to put into reality “a
third way,” this utopian dream of all socialists and progressives, based on a
belief in a fuzzy combination of plan and market.
That reform
led to the weakening of the planning system and to the increased independence
of firms, most of them state owned. It was movement in the right direction. The
Soviet politicians and our own hardliners criticized the reform from the left.
The Czech economists of my generation (I founded and became president of the
Club of Young Economists) criticized the reform from the right, for its evident
insufficiency and inconsistency.
At that
moment, in the mid-1960s, we discovered the famous dispute about socialism, the
so-called socialist calculation debate, between the Austrian economists Ludwig
von Mises and F. A. Hayek on one side and the socialists Oskar Lange and Abba
P. Lerner on the other, during the 1930s. This debate gave us many powerful
arguments about the impossibility of economic calculation under socialism and
about the futility of the idea of playing at markets instead of introducing a
real market.
It enhanced
the doubts we were developing from observing the evident inefficiency of our
own economic system. It is a pity that this famous debate is not required
reading for contemporary students. The highly regulated and subsidized
economies in Europe (and in this country as well) should be discussed in light
of Hayek’s arguments.
The real
revelation came when we came across Hayek’s article “The Use of Knowledge in
Society,” originally published in 1945. You may ask how it was possible to get
access to such articles in a totalitarian communist regime. Yet, it was
possible.
We scholars
couldn’t get our hands on the Wall Street Journal, Newsweek, or Time, but in the
libraries of academic institutions we could get the American Economic Review and similar journals.
They were sufficiently scientific as to be incomprehensible for the communist
censors. Even now, I give this article to my students as the best introduction
to rational economic thinking. The impossibility of centralizing dispersed knowledge
is one of the most important ideas in economic science, comparable to the
classic formulations of Adam Smith.
BRINGING HAYEK TO LIFE IN PRAGUE
Our relatively far-reaching, and for that time, unique economic reforms led to significant changes in political life as well. In this respect, we got a lot of inspiration from Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom.
Our relatively far-reaching, and for that time, unique economic reforms led to significant changes in political life as well. In this respect, we got a lot of inspiration from Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom.
That book
was illegally and unofficially translated in my country in the 1960s. It was
widely read, and — what is even more important — it was understood as a
decisive and final rejection of all kinds of totalitarianism, collectivism, and
interventionism and as an authoritative defense of liberty. At least it was
understood that way by my generation, which saw its task differently from
students in Western Europe and America at that time. We wanted to introduce
capitalism, not to destroy it.
Our
promising era did not last long. On the morning of August 21, 1968, the armies
of the Soviet Union and other Warsaw Pact countries invaded Czechoslovakia and
crushed the so-called Prague Spring. That was, paradoxically, the first and
only time I saw Hayek.
I happened
to attend a conference in the beautiful Austrian ski resort of Alpbach, which
was the Austrian, much smaller version of today’s World Economic Forum in Davos.
That is where I heard about the brutal occupation of my country and about the
collapse of our plans and dreams to get rid of communism. A group of
Czechoslovak participants stayed there for the following few days, not knowing
what to do. Some of us decided to return home, some decided to emigrate. As an
irony of history, the very next day after the invasion, Hayek was scheduled to
speak at the conference.
This was in
the years between The Constitution of Liberty and Law, Legislation, and Liberty, when his thinking
focused on rules and order. So his speech was probably better suited for
sophisticated constitutional lawyers than for a young economist from communist
Czechoslovakia. I sat down in the auditorium, saw Hayek, heard his voice, but
was not able to concentrate on his complicated argumentation. My head was full
of thoughts about my occupied country.
It took us
20 long years to finally get rid of communism and of our Soviet oppressors.
When this happened, I was, accidentally, again in Austria. The day before the
student demonstration in Prague in November 1989 that started our Velvet
Revolution, I was giving a lecture at the University of Linz. During my meeting
with the economics professors in the afternoon, I asked them about the role of
the Austrian School of Economics and of Hayek in the country where he was born
and where he spent an important part of his life. Their answer was very
depressing: “Hayek is dead in Austria now. He is not on our reading list
anymore.”
In the
evening, the university organized a panel discussion about the then ongoing
reforms in Central and Eastern Europe. Several hundred students attended. In
answering one of the questions, I made an unprepared but prophetic statement:
“If Hayek is dead in Austria, we will bring him to life in Prague very soon.”
Of course, I did not know what would happen in Prague the next evening.
TRANSFORMATION FROM BELOW
Very rapidly — in the middle of December, when the first noncommunist government was formed — we started dismantling communism and its institutions. As minister of finance in charge of the transformation of the Czechoslovak economic system, I was — at least I hope — truly Hayekian. My radical reform program was to liberalize, to deregulate, to privatize, and to de-subsidize the economy.
Very rapidly — in the middle of December, when the first noncommunist government was formed — we started dismantling communism and its institutions. As minister of finance in charge of the transformation of the Czechoslovak economic system, I was — at least I hope — truly Hayekian. My radical reform program was to liberalize, to deregulate, to privatize, and to de-subsidize the economy.
We also
understood that Hayek’s concepts of spontaneous order, of dispersed knowledge,
of human action versus human design, were relevant not only for the
understanding of normal functioning of a free economic and social system, but
also for the process of its transformation. It became evident that the
transformation of a complex system cannot be organized from above. The
long-prepared sophisticated reform blueprints became — practically overnight —
irrelevant. Such a transformation process is inevitably a complicated mixture
of spontaneity and constructivism, and it must follow the logic of Hayekian
evolution rather than the dreams of the always ready to be involved
constructivists.
I dare say
that we more or less succeeded in our task — more rapidly and with lower costs
than the other post-communist countries. The country became a parliamentary
democracy and market economy relatively soon. Just as we started that process,
Hayek published his last book, The Fatal Conceit,
which — I have to admit — I have never found time to read. Communism was a
fatal conceit, undoubtedly, but for me, and for many of us, it was already
over. “The impossibility of centralizing dispersed knowledge is one of the most
important ideas in economic science.”
We were
preoccupied with the task of building a different society, and we assumed —
correctly or incorrectly — that we knew enough about “the errors of socialism”
(which was the subtitle of his book).
I don’t want
to say that Hayek is not relevant now. I do believe that he is as important and
worth studying as he was in the past. We are again in a world which is based on
a new, perhaps only slightly new conceit. Today’s society in Europe, and I am
afraid more and more in America as well, is based on a similar error as in the
past. Hayek was right in The Road to Serfdom that
interventionism is a very unstable system, which inevitably evolves away from a
free market economy (and society) into a more and more controlled, regulated,
and administered system. This truth should never be forgotten. We should read
Hayek again and again.
The economic
system in Europe at the beginning of the 21st century is not a free market
economy, but a “social-market economy” (soziale Marktwirtschaft)
with a very heavy load of environmentalism in it. Such a system is not tenable;
it cannot function in the long run at all, and it cannot function efficiently
in the short run. Europe’s sluggish economic growth — currently even stagnation,
high unemployment, and increasing indebtedness — are the inevitable (and
expected) outcomes. The tragic mistake — the attempt to monetarily unify Europe
by introducing a common European currency — made it only more visible and more
rapidly moving towards the end.
Hayek’s
ideas returned to public attention also with the financial and economic crisis
at the end of the last decade (which my country survived relatively well). It
seems evident that Hayek proved to be more relevant than Keynes in the analysis
of the causes of such a crisis. Hayek tells us that a crisis is usually the
result of “easy money policy,” of the irresponsible playing with interest rates
and of the dream that fiscal policy can substitute for the much needed
restructuring of the economy. He would no doubt consider the currently popular
“quantitative easing” a pseudo-medicine. Those who do not know it should reread
his Prices and Production, published 80 years ago.
Europe needs
Hayek and his merciless analysis of the over regulated, controlled, centrally
administered European economic system and of the slippery road to serfdom that
we have already embarked on. And I hope that American students, too, will come
to understand this new “fatal” conceit.
No comments:
Post a Comment