Why it’s inevitable and why postponing it will exacerbate its consequences
by Martin Hutchinson
Washington has been consumed by negotiations about avoiding a debt default. On all sides we are told how irresponsible and disastrous it would be to allow the United States to default on its debt obligations. That's quite correct: it would be irresponsible and disastrous. But given the fiscal and monetary policies of the last five years, and the slim-to-none chance of getting them reversed in the near future, such a default is inevitable in the long run. Thus we might as well get it over with, since the earlier we default, the smaller the amount of wealth and living standards that will be wiped out.
Washington has been consumed by negotiations about avoiding a debt default. On all sides we are told how irresponsible and disastrous it would be to allow the United States to default on its debt obligations. That's quite correct: it would be irresponsible and disastrous. But given the fiscal and monetary policies of the last five years, and the slim-to-none chance of getting them reversed in the near future, such a default is inevitable in the long run. Thus we might as well get it over with, since the earlier we default, the smaller the amount of wealth and living standards that will be wiped out.
The excess of government debt isn't just a U.S. problem, far from it.
The IMF's Fiscal Monitor "Taxing Times" released this week, sets out
the bloating of government debt worldwide over the last five years. U.S.
gross public debt has increased from 73.3% of GDP in 2008 to a projected 106.7%
of GDP in 2013, an increase of 33.4 percentage points, or 6.7 percentage points
a year. That's not as large as the total deficits, because even if real GDP
hasn't grown much, nominal GDP has, reducing the debt/GDP ratio.
The 1970s, in this respect, were in retrospect a healthy period, in
which the large budget deficits (but nothing like as large as recently) were
wiped out by inflation, so the U.S. debt/GDP ratio actually fell. Compared to
the 1970s, the last few years have seen even slower growth, low but not zero
inflation and budget deficits (from the middle of this decade to be joined by
rapidly growing social security and Medicare deficits) a multiple of their
1970s size. In consequence, the debt/GDP ratio has grown at a rapid clip.
6.7 percentage points a year is a LOT; it's more than double the rate of
growth of nominal GDP, which itself includes a chunk of inflation. Thus the
rise in debt is swallowing more than twice as much as the economy generates in
new output each year. Needless to say, this is completely unsustainable.
The problem is not confined to the U.S. Britain's problem is almost as
bad; gross debt there increased from 51.9% of GDP in 2008 to a projected 82.1%
of GDP, an increase of 30.2 percentage points, or 6.2 percentage points a
year—again double the increase in nominal GDP, which in Britain has consisted
almost entirely of inflation. This is not due to British
"austerity"—policies since May 2010 have slowed the debt increase
somewhat, but killed the economy, since they involved heavy tax rises and very
few genuine spending cuts.
The eurozone's performance as a whole has not been quite as bad—the debt/GDP
ratio has increased by 25.4 percentage points, or 5.1 percentage points a
year—still more than double the eurozone's feeble nominal GDP growth.
Then there's Japan, with the world's worst performance other than the
true basket cases like Greece. Japan's debt has increased since 2008 from
191.7% of GDP to 243.5% of GDP, an increase of a staggering 10.4 percentage
points of GDP per annum, with debt absorbing around four times the feeble
Japanese growth in nominal GDP. Abenomics isn't going to solve the problem
either; the foolish Shinzo Abe recently announced that he was going to allow
the modest increase in sales tax scheduled for May 2014 to go ahead, but would
offset its effect with a special "stimulus" spending program of
around $50 billion. Japanese politicians appear to have read no economist other
than Maynard Keynes; far from being "stimulative," Abe's combined
tax-and-spend program simply diverts massive resources from productive private
uses to unproductive public uses. It will certainly shrink rather than grow the
private sector, from which all tax revenues and government delights are
ultimately derived.
Economic optimists will suggest we should take account of net debt
rather than gross debt. By that standard the U.S. debt increase in the last
five years is worse at 7.0% a year, Britain's worse at 7.4%, the eurozone's
slightly better at 4.2% and Japan's also slightly better, but still terrible at
8.9% annually. However net debt isn't a very useful number when central bank
after central bank is engaging in "stimulus" debt purchases; the fact
that debt is located in the central bank rather than the market makes the
financing problem temporarily easier, but doesn't alter the deficit that led
originally to the problem, and may eventually lead to a massive new problem as
the central bank's balance sheet collapses into ruin.
Skeptics will ask why this situation should end. After all, debt levels
have been increasing for more than a decade, and the rate of increase has
slowed considerably since the first stimulative enthusiasm of 2009-10. Current
policies, with Janet Yellen likely to be confirmed to lead the Fed until
January 2018 and Barack Obama President until January 2017, are presumably set
for the next several years.
On fiscal policy, the Republicans are proving themselves unable to make
substantial progress, even when they want to, against the spending leviathan
driven by the Democrats. On monetary policy, September's wimp-out on
"tapering" of bond purchases, when you read the Minutes of the meeting,
shows pretty clearly that absent a major outbreak of inflation, the Fed under
its current or incoming management will always find an excuse to continue
current levels of asset purchases, or even to increase them. The Fed's
admirers, on monetary policy, including a substantial fraction of today's
Republican Party, see no reason why this should be a problem. After all, if the
Fed can sustain a balance sheet of $3.7 trillion, today's value, why should it
not sustain a balance sheet of $8 trillion, its value in January 2018 if asset
purchases continue as at present?
By 2018, U.S. gross debt will be 140% of GDP, at present rates of
progress (the Congressional Budget Office has a much lower figure, but it
assumes fiscal discipline and quite rapid growth with no recession). That's a
fairly frightening number—it's higher than ever in U.S. history, above the 1945
peak. On its own, however, it does not suggest imminent default—more than a
decade would still have to elapse until U.S. debt reached the levels of Japan
today, or of Britain in 1815 and 1945, both of which were negotiated without
default (helped by an impossibly austere government by modern democratic
standards in the first case and by inflation and financial repression in the
second).
However the global bond markets are interconnected and are becoming more
so. Commentators on Japan's JGB government bond market remark that the vast
majority of investors are domestic, but with the aging of the Japanese
population, savings rates have dropped precipitously and are now very low
indeed. Given the continued size of Japan's budget deficits, being increased by
Abe's foolish "stimulus," an increasing proportion of Japan's debt
must be financed internationally. This has two effects. First, it forces up
Japanese debt yields, which in any case must rise from their current level of
below 1% on ten-year debt as inflation takes hold. Second, it causes
international institutions to cast a beady eye on Japan's finances.
They won't like what they see. Based on the past five years, by 2018
Japan's gross debt to GDP ratio will be 295.3%, above the 1815/1945 British
peak of about 250%, and even its net debt will be 184.5%, with a huge overhang
of debt held by the Bank of Japan. That debt will have sagged in value as interest
rates rise, and future prospects for international investors will be for more
price declines and increasing risk. At that point, it won't matter what Japan's
domestic savers do; even its gigantic government-controlled banks and insurance
companies will not be able to offset a buyers' strike by the international
market. Like Greece in 2010/12, Japan will be forced to default.
When Japan defaults international investors will examine much more carefully the debt obligations of other countries on a similar trajectory to Japan, just as Greece's default caused them to look skeptically at Spain, Portugal, Ireland and Italy. There will however be no sugar-daddy European Central Bank to bail out the U.S. and Britain; those countries' own central banks will be far too compromised by their gigantic debt holdings, and nobody else will be anything like large enough. A Japanese default will thus lead in very short order to U.S. and British defaults.
When Japan defaults international investors will examine much more carefully the debt obligations of other countries on a similar trajectory to Japan, just as Greece's default caused them to look skeptically at Spain, Portugal, Ireland and Italy. There will however be no sugar-daddy European Central Bank to bail out the U.S. and Britain; those countries' own central banks will be far too compromised by their gigantic debt holdings, and nobody else will be anything like large enough. A Japanese default will thus lead in very short order to U.S. and British defaults.
If default is inevitable within 5 years or so, it's much more sensible
to get it over with quickly. The write-down on outstanding debt will be much
less, as will the write-offs of other assets that are hopelessly overvalued in
a world where the U.S. government cannot pay its debts on time. The inevitable
deep recession will be correspondingly less painful. What's more, debt default
will force the U.S. government to live within its means, running a budget
surplus on a cash-in-cash-out basis, not created through funny accounting.
The necessary reforms in entitlements would be made immediately, rather
than being delayed until the Social Security and Medicare trust funds run out.
Reforms would be made in such avenues of fraud as food stamps, whose recipients
have increased from 28 million to 48 million in the last five years. (That 20
million increase compares with a 12.8 million increase in the number of
unemployed, including those "not participating in the labor force.")
Of course, the immense bloat in other Federal programs would be eliminated.
President Obama would doubtless object and attempt to prevent this, but a
government that has defaulted cannot borrow money, and must live within its
means. If necessary, bailiffs from the People's Bank of China would seize the
White House and evict the inhabitants.
Under current policies, a U.S. debt default is inevitable, probably
within five years. Since we can't change the policies, we're better off
defaulting now. Tea-Partiers, more power to your elbow!
No comments:
Post a Comment