The “Unintended” But Entirely Predictable Effects
by Robert P. Murphy
Near the end of Human Action Ludwig von Mises
declared that it was the “primary civic duty” to learn the teachings of
economics. The public’s growing furor over the Patient Protection and
Affordable Care Act — popularly known as “ObamaCare” — beautifully illustrates
Mises’s point. No one has any business being shocked — shocked! — that millions of Americans will lose their current
health insurance (including the present, irritated, writer), because such
an outcome was obvious all along. Furthermore, the hilarious snags with
healthcare.gov are merely a sideshow; the true problems with ObamaCare run much
deeper than a malfunctioning website.
The Basic Structure of “ObamaCare”
The Affordable Care Act (ACA) was formally signed into
law on March 23, 2010. There are numerous provisions that kick in at various stages, through 2020.
For our purposes in this article, there are four key elements of the ACA that
merit our attention:
· Insurers are legally required to provide coverage to all applicants, regardless of medical history, with a partial “community rating” system for premiums, which means that insurers must set premiums based (mostly) on geography and age, rather than sex and (most) pre-existing conditions.
· Health insurance policies must meet minimum standards (called “essential health benefits”), including no caps on annual or lifetime payments from the insurance companies for an individual policy.
· Everyone is required to obtain health insurance, except for waivers granted for certain religious groups and those deemed to be unable to afford coverage. Government subsidies and state-based “health exchange markets” will be provided to assist individuals.
· An “employer mandate” penalizes firms with 50 or more employees if they do not offer coverage for their full-time employees, defined as those working 30 or more hours per week.
Intended
Consequences
There are reasons for the particular provisions above,
which sound superficially sensible (if you don’t know much about economics).
Obviously, before the passage of the new law, there were millions of people
without health insurance coverage. Although many of them were young and healthy
— thinking they could risk going without coverage — many of them wanted
coverage but couldn’t obtain it, either because of the price or an outright
refusal of coverage because of a pre-existing condition.
Now, given that the
government wanted to mandate that health insurers provide coverage to all
applicants, there had to be specific rules on what premiums they could charge,
and minimums on the type of policies offered. Otherwise, the health insurers
could say, “Fair enough, President Obama, we will indeed give a policy to any
applicant — even someone with brain cancer. It’s just that the annual premium
for people with brain cancer will be $2 million, and we will cap our total
payment at $100 per year. Who wants to sign up? We’re more than happy to comply
with the new mandate.”
Moving down the list, let’s consider the individual mandate, which requires that (just
about) every American carries health insurance. The reason for this provision
is to avoid what’s known as adverse selection.
If health insurers were required to provide coverage to all applicants, with
(partial) community rating, and if
individuals retained the freedom to buy coverage or not, then the private
health insurance companies would quickly go out of business. Healthy people
could drop their coverage, saving on the hefty premiums each year, and then
apply for health insurance whenever they got sick. This would be analogous to
people buying car insurance only after they’d
gotten in an accident; it clearly wouldn’t work for any firm to offer insurance
in this environment.
But, given that the
government is going to mandate that (virtually) all individuals obtain health
insurance, it was necessary to offer subsidies and other mechanisms to make
sure this mandate was feasible.
Finally, the employer mandate was ostensibly included,
in order to minimize the disruption to the existing system. In the absence of
an employer mandate, people feared that employers would drop their original
health insurance plans, telling their employees to sign up at the state-based
“health exchanges.” The reason for limiting the employer mandate to large firms
(50 or more full-time employees) and their full-time employees (those working
30 or more hours) is that it would be unreasonable and counterproductive to
impose such expensive requirements — which could be thousands of dollars
annually, per worker — on small businesses or even a large firm concerning only
its part-time workers.
The “Unintended” But Entirely Predictable Effects
We are now seeing many of the undesirable effects of
the ACA. These are typically being described as “unintended.” However, this
adjective is a bit of a misnomer, since these outcomes were entirely
predictable, and in fact were predicted
by many free-market economists in the debate leading up to the passage of the
ACA. Cynics can justifiably speculate that at least some of the proponents of
the ACA knew full well the outcome would be untenable, leading the public to
embrace even more federal intervention in health care down the road.
The most obvious result is a large spike in premiums
for many people, once the mandates on health coverage are fully phased in. The
biggest hit will occur in places that right now offer bare-bones catastrophic
policies with large deductibles and low caps. For example, according to this CNN article, officials in
Florida estimated that the premiums on a “silver” plan would rise anywhere from
7.6 percent to 58.8 percent, while officials in Ohio estimated an average
increase of 41 percent.
Now even if the official amount that certain
individuals pay for their health insurance goes down,
the real question is whether this is more than offset by the increase in taxes necessary to cover all of the
new subsidies to poor individuals who cannot afford to meet the individual
mandate. Step back and look at the big picture: Under the ACA, suddenly
millions of new people are going to be seeking more medical care than they did
before. There’s nothing in the new law that will magically create more doctors,
hospitals, or MRI machines. Americans in general are going to pay for this, one
way or another. Indeed, the huge increase in government responsibility for health
spending will provide the justification for government-imposed rationing down
the road — as even Paul Krugman acknowledges when he cheekily
calls for death panels. (Really, click on the link to see the video if you
don’t believe me.)
“But the President Said I Could Keep My Plan …”
Another predictable outcome is that many Americans
will not be able to keep their previous plan. Millions of Americans who bought
insurance in the individual market (i.e., not via their employer) will find
that their plan doesn’t meet the standards of ObamaCare. To keep premiums down,
relatively young and healthy, self-employed individuals had “catastrophic”
plans with high deductibles. These are no longer legally allowed. According to this Forbes article, as far back as
2010 (sic!) Obama officials were projecting that 93 million Americans had health insurance plans
that would be unacceptable under ObamaCare.
Job Losses
Besides rate hikes (and ultimately, government
rationing of medical care), another major downside of the ACA is the job losses
it will cause. For example, here is an email that a fellow economist sent to Greg Mankiw of Harvard:
With the implementation of the ACA (Affordable Care Act) these institutions are giving notification to their part-time faculty that their individual teaching schedules will now be limited to three sections. At the college this will likely result in the cancellation of 20-25% of the class sections in economics, and I would assume other areas will have a similar result. The students are not fully aware of the situation and many will be surprised that their desire to get a college education is now being impacted by the need to avoid the full implementation of the ACA. [Emphasis added]
Even some labor
leaders recognize the devastation ObamaCare would wreak
on workers, protesting to the government that it would “destroy the foundation
of the 40-hour work week.”
This isn’t rocket science, as they say. If the
government has to force employers to provide a benefit to their employees, it
means it’s unprofitable; otherwise the employers would have already done it as
part of their compensation package in order to attract quality workers. So if
this costly, unprofitable employer mandate only applies to firms with 50 or
more employees, and even then only applies to those employees who work 30 or
more hours, then we shouldn’t be shocked — shocked! — to discover firms not
growing past 49 employees, and/or limiting people to 29 hours per week.
No comments:
Post a Comment