The state will continue to grow relentlessly if people are convinced that at the very least it is a necessary evil
One of my favorite quotes from the quotable Thomas Paine is a mere
footnote in his treatise, Rights of Man, Part
Second, in which he wrote:
It is scarcely possible to touch on any subject, that will not suggest an allusion to some corruption in governments.
Paine was referring to “the splendor of
the throne,” which he said “is no other than the corruption of the state.
It is made up of a band of parasites, living in luxurious indolence, out of the
public taxes.” He thought the U.S. federal government, newly created by
the Constitution, provided hope against political corruption because of the
limitations it imposed on the government. Paine was in England at the
time and had no idea that the new government, whose intellectual leader was
Alexander Hamilton, was busy interpreting those limitations out of existence.
Paine also didn’t know the Constitutional
Convention of 1787 was in fact a coup d'état. The participants had been
authorized only to amend the Articles of Confederation, but the nationalists,
at least, wanted to replace the Articles with a new government that would be
more “energetic.” Knowing that Washington’s presence at the convention
would be critical to its success, Henry Knox told the retired general that he
would be given the president’s chair, and moreover, that he would not be
presiding over some middling conference of officials tinkering with the
“present defective confederation,” but instead would lead a prestigious body of
men as they created an “energetic and judicious system,” one which would
“doubly” entitle him to be called The Father of His Country.
In a previous note Knox had awakened
Washington’s interest by lying about the meaning of Shays’s Rebellion.
According to Knox, former Revolutionary War officer Daniel Shays had organized
the riffraff of Western Massachusetts to shut down the courts to avoid paying
their taxes. They were levelers, Knox said, who sought to annihilate all
debts through “the weakness of government.” Washington, who owned some
60,000 acres in the Virginia backcountry, thought that such people were “a
wretched lot, not to be trusted, and certainly not to be the bone and sinew of
a great nation.”
In truth, as historian Leonard L.
Richards has shown, Shays’s Rebellion was not an uprising of poor indebted farmers, but a
protest against the Massachusetts state government and its attempt to enrich
the few at the expense of the many through a regressive tax system. The
rebellion began as peaceful petitioning and escalated into violence only after
the state repeatedly ignored the petitions. Though they were described in
various disparaging terms, the rebels saw themselves as regulators whose purpose was “the suppressing of
tyrannical government in the Massachusetts State.” They drew their
inspiration from the Declaration of Independence that said people should throw
off any government that is destructive of their rights.
But the rebellion was finally crushed and
has since been interpreted as proof that a stronger central government was
necessary. Following ratification, “We the people” were headed down the
long road to serfdom at an accelerated pace.
Is there an exit on that road?
A few thinkers have argued that there is.
In 1849 in Paris, Gustav de Molinari and
his laissez-faire colleagues met to discuss Molinari’s new book, Les Soirées de la Rue Saint-Lazare, a series of fictional dialogues between
a conservative, a socialist, and himself, whom he referred to as the economist.
Molinari argued that the free market could produce the state’s traditional
function of security without monopoly, or as he put it in another essay, “the production of security should . . .
remain subject to the law of free competition.”
His friends at the meeting included
Charles Coquelin, Frederic Bastiat, and Charles Dunoyer. None of them
accepted his thesis. In the absence of a monopoly state, Coquelin
asserted, competition was “impossible to put into practice or even to conceive
of it.” Bastiat said the only way to guarantee justice and security is
with force, and that requires a “supreme power,” not spread over bodies “equal
amongst themselves.” Coquelin later wrote a review of
Molinari’s arguments, correctly describing the latter’s position as one in
which
the State would be nothing but a kind of insurance company, a rival to
many others, and each person would, just as he pleases, freely subscribe to
this one or to that one to guarantee himself against the troubles that threaten
him, exactly as one would guarantee his house against fire or his ship against
shipwreck.
Murray Rothbard describes the
Belgian-born Molinari as the most “consistent, longest-lived and most prolific
of the French laissez-faire economists.” He was proposing life without a
state, and there were virtually no takers.
Almost simultaneously in England a young
Herbert Spencer was advancing a nearly identical thesis in his book, Social Statics. Spencer argued that government
would inevitably become smaller and “decay” as the voluntary institutions of
the market replaced it. As David Hart points out, “it must be assumed that the two thinkers
arrived at their positions independently of one another, suggesting that
anti-statism is inherent in the logic of the free market.”
A disciple of Spencer’s, Auberon Herbert,
agreed with Molinari that the market, unhampered by the state, could satisfy every
want that we have, including protection services. David Hart:
Neither Spencer nor Herbert went as far as Molinari's suggestion that
these voluntary defense agencies would be fully professional business
organizations whose prices would be determined on the market by competition.
They merely limited themselves to criticizing the monopoly of the state and
arguing that the individual had the right to organize freely.
However reasonable their views might
sound, they never had a wide following. Molinari believed that the state
would die a natural death, that full liberty and a free market were inevitable,
yet in the last half of the 19th Century, he witnessed the rise of statism in
all its virulent forms. David Hart:
Molinari had well understood the fact that these
groups which controlled or had access to the state, comprised a class which
would not willingly give up the privileges that power bestowed.
Unfortunately, he had badly over-estimated the readiness of the exploited
classes, the workers, the consumers and the industrialists who did not seek
state privileges, to identify government intervention as the enemy of
progress. [emphasis added]
The State: Protector or Predator?
Before dismissing Molinari as a hopeless
idealist, we should refresh ourselves on what the state actually is. As
Rothbard has written in “The Anatomy of the State,” one can acquire economic goods either
by production or predation. Following the line of thought of German
sociologist Franz Oppenheimer, Rothbard says the state, as a monopolist of
violence, “is the systematization of the predatory process over a given
territory.” More precisely,
The State provides a legal, orderly, systematic channel for the
predation of private property; it renders certain, secure, and relatively
"peaceful" the lifeline of the parasitic caste in society.
With this understanding, it's hardly
surprising that the state’s biggest problem is ideological. To stay in
control, it needs the support of the majority of its subjects, even if such
support is only grudging acceptance. Political leaders alone cannot
muster the needed support. The rulers need intellectuals to persuade the
masses that the state is “good, wise and, at least, inevitable, and certainly
better than other conceivable alternatives.” In return for this support,
the state sees that its intellectuals are well-taken care of.
From this it follows that the greatest
danger to the state is the person who publicly proclaims the nakedness of the
emperor.
This is our cue. The state will
continue to grow relentlessly if people are convinced that at the very least it
is a necessary evil, as Paine once put it. But the state’s abundant
historical record is clear: It isn’t at all necessary. It is simply evil.
No comments:
Post a Comment