Paper money eventually returns to its intrinsic value — zero
by Frank Hollenbeck
Today, anyone who talks about hyperinflation is treated
like the shepherd boy who cried wolf. When the wolf actually does show up,
though, belated warnings will do little to keep the flock safe.
The current Federal Reserve strategy is apparently to
wait for significant price inflation to show up in the consumer price index
before tapering. Yet history tells us that you treat inflation like a sunburn.
You don’t wait for your skin to turn red to take action. You protect yourself
before leaving home. Once inflation really picks up steam, it becomes almost
impossible to control as the politics and economics of the situation combine to
make the urge to print irresistible.
The hyperinflation of 1790s France illustrates one way
in which inflationary monetary policy becomes unmanageable in an environment of
economic stagnation and debt, and in the face of special interests who benefit
from, and demand, easy money.
In 1789, France found itself in a situation of heavy
debt and serious deficits. At the time, France had the strongest and shrewdest
financial minds of the time. They were keenly aware of the risks of printing
fiat currency since they had experienced just decades earlier the disastrous
Mississippi Bubble under the guidance of John Law.
France had learned how easy it is to issue paper money
and nearly impossible to keep it in check. Thus, the debate over the first
issuance of the paper money, known as assignats, in April 1790 was heated, and
only passed because the new currency (paying 3 percent interest to the holder) was
collateralized by the land stolen from the church and fugitive aristocracy.
This land constituted almost a third of France and was located in the best
places.
Once the assignats were issued, business activity
picked up, but within five months the French government was again in financial
trouble. The first issuance was considered a rousing success, just like the
first issuance of paper money under John Law. However, the debate over the
second issuance during the month of September 1790 was even more chaotic since
many remembered the slippery slope to hyperinflation. Additional constraints
were added to satisfy the naysayers. For example, once land was purchased by
French citizens, the payment in currency was to be destroyed to take the new
paper currency out of circulation.
The second issuance caused an even greater
depreciation of the currency but new complaints arose that not enough money was
circulating to conduct transactions. Also, the overflowing government coffers
resulting from all this new paper money led to demands for a slew of new
government programs, wise or foolish, for the “good of the people.” The promise
to take paper money out of circulation was quickly abandoned, and different
districts in France independently started to issue their own assignats.
Prices started to rise and cries for more circulating
medium became deafening. Although the first two issuances almost failed,
additional issuances became easier and easier.
Many Frenchman soon became eternal optimists claiming
that inflation was prosperity, like the drunk forgetting the inevitable
hangover. Although every new issuance initially boosted economic activity, the
improved business conditions became shorter and shorter after each new
issuance. Commercial activity soon became spasmodic: one manufacturer after
another closed shop. Money was losing its store-of-value function, making
business decisions extremely difficult in an environment of uncertainty.
Foreigners were blamed and heavy taxes were levied against foreign goods. The
great manufacturing centers of Normandy closed down and the rest of France
speedily followed, throwing vast numbers of workers into bread lines. The
collapse of manufacturing and commerce was quick, and occurred only a few
months after the second issuance of assignats and followed the same path as
Austria, Russia, America, and all other countries that had previously tried to
gain prosperity on a mountain of paper.
Social norms also changed dramatically with the French
turning to speculation and gambling. Vast fortunes were built speculating and
gambling on borrowed money. A vast debtor class emerged located mostly in the
largest cities.
To purchase government land, only a small down payment
was necessary with the rest to be paid in fixed installments. These debtors
quickly saw the benefit of a depreciating currency. Inflation erodes the real
value of any fixed payment. Why work for a living and take the risk of building
a business when speculating on stocks or land can bring wealth instantaneously
and with almost no effort? This growing segment of nouveau riche quickly used its newfound wealth to
gain political power to ensure that the printing presses never stopped. They
soon took control and corruption became rampant.
Of course, blame for the ensuing inflation was
assigned to everything but the real cause. Shopkeepers and merchants were
blamed for higher prices. In 1793, 200 stores in Paris were looted and one
French politician proclaimed “shopkeepers were only giving back to the people
what they had hitherto robbed them of.” Price controls (the “law of the maximum”)
were ultimately imposed, and shortages soon abounded everywhere. Ration tickets
were issued on necessities such as bread, sugar, soap, wood, or coal.
Shopkeepers risked their heads if they hinted at a price higher than the
official price. The daily ledger of those executed with the guillotine included
many small business owners who violated the law of the maximum. To detect goods
concealed by farmers and shopkeepers, a spy system was established with the
informant receiving 1/3 of the goods recovered. A farmer could see his crop
seized if he did not bring it to market, and was lucky to escape with his life.
Everything was enormously inflated in price except the
wages for labor. As manufacturers closed, wages collapsed. Those who did not
have the means, foresight, or skill to transfer their worthless paper into real
assets were driven into poverty. By 1797, most of the currency was in the hands
of the working class and the poor. The entire episode was a massive transfer of
real wealth from the poor to the rich, similar to what we are experiencing in
Western societies today.
The French government tried to issue a new currency
called the mandat, but by May 1797 both currencies were virtually worthless.
Once the dike was broken, the money poured through and the currency was swollen
beyond control. As Voltaire once said, “Paper money eventually returns to its
intrinsic value — zero.” In France, it took nearly 40 years to bring capital,
industry, commerce, and credit back up to the level attained in 1789.
No comments:
Post a Comment