With the
resurgence of Keynesian economic policy as a response to the current crisis,
echoes of past debates are being heard—in particular the debate from the 1930s
between John Maynard Keynes and Friedrich Hayek. Keynes talked about the
“capital stock” of the economy. He argued that by stimulating spending on
outputs (consumption goods and services), one can increase productive
investment to meet that spending, thus adding to the capital stock and
increasing employment.
Hayek accused
Keynes of insufficient attention to the nature of capital in production. (By
“capital” I mean the physical production structure of the economy, including
machinery, buildings, raw materials, and human capital—skills). Hayek pointed
out that capital investment does not simply add to production in a general way
but rather is embodied in concrete capital items. That is, the productive
capital of the economy is not simply an amorphous “stock” of generalized
production power; it is an intricate structure of specific interrelated
complementary components. Stimulating spending and investment, then, amounts to
stimulating specific sections and components of this intricate structure.
The “shape” of production is changed by stimulatory activist spending. And given that in a world of scarcity productive resources are not free, this change comes at the expense of productive effort elsewhere. The pattern of production thus gets out of sync with the pattern of consumption, and eventually this must lead to a collapse. Productive sectors, like dot-com startups or residential housing, become “overbought” (while other sectors develop less), and eventually a “correction” must occur. Add this distortion to the fact that the original stimulus must somehow eventually be paid for, and we have a predictable bust.
These Hayekian
criticisms are once again relevant. It is necessary therefore to return to the
nature of capital to clarify the issues. Hayek was working from foundations
that were developed by his intellectual forebears in the Austrian school of
economics. Specifically, it is the Austrian theory of capital that is relevant,
and we should begin with that.
The Austrian Theory
The best known
Austrian capital theorist was Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, though his teacher Carl
Menger is the one who got the ball rolling, providing the central idea that
Böhm-Bawerk elaborated. Böhm-Bawerk produced three volumes dedicated to the
study of capital and interest, making the Austrian theory of capital his
best-known theoretical contribution. He provided a detailed account of the
fundamentals of capitalistic production. Later contributors include Hayek,
Ludwig Lachmann, and Israel Kirzner. They added to and enriched Böhm-Bawerk’s
account in crucial ways. The legacy we now have is a rich tapestry that accords
amazingly well with the nature of production in the digital information age.
Some current contributors along these lines include Peter Klein, Nicolai Foss,
Howard Baetjer, and me.
The Austrians
emphasize that production takes time: The more indirect it is, the more “time”
it takes. Production today is much more “roundabout” (Böhm-Bawerk’s term) than
older, more rudimentary production processes. Rather than picking fruit in our
backyard and eating it, most of us today get it from fruit farms that use
complex picking, sorting, and packing machinery to process carefully engineered
fruits. Consider the amount of “time” (for example in “people-hours”) involved
in setting up and assembling all the pieces of this complex production process
from scratch—from before the manufacture of the machines and so on. This gives
us some idea of what is meant by production methods that are “roundabout.”
(The scare quotes
around time are used because in fact there is no perfectly rigorous way to
define the length of a production process in purely physical terms. But,
intuitively, what is being asserted is that doing things in a more complicated,
specialized way is more difficult; loosely speaking it takes more “time”
because it is more “roundabout,” more indirect.)
More Roundabout Production
Through countless
self-interested individual production decisions, we have adopted more
roundabout methods of production because they are more productive—they add more
value—than less roundabout methods. Were this not the case, they would not be
deemed worth the sacrifice and effort of the “time” involved—and would be
abandoned in favor of more direct production methods. What are at work here are
the benefits of specialization—the division of labor to which Adam Smith
referred. Modern economies comprise complex, specialized processes in which the
many steps necessary to produce any product are connected in a sequentially
specific network—some things have to be done before others. There is a time
structure to the capital structure.
This intricate
time structure is partially organized, partially spontaneous (organic). Every
production process is the result of some multiperiod plan. Entrepreneurs
envision the possibility of providing (new, improved, cheaper) products to
consumers whose expenditure on them will be more than sufficient to cover the
cost of producing them. In pursuit of this vision the entrepreneur plans to
assemble the necessary capital items in a synergistic combination. These
capital combinations are structurally composed modules that are the ingredients
of the industry-wide or economy-wide capital structure. The latter is the
result then of the dynamic interaction of multiple entrepreneurial plans in the
marketplace; it is what constitutes the market process. Some plans will prove
more successful than others, some will have to be modified to some degree, some
will fail. What emerges is a structure that is not planned by anyone in its
totality but is the result of many individual actions in the pursuit of profit.
It is an unplanned structure that has a logic, a coherence, to it. It was not
designed, and could not have been designed, by any human mind or committee of
minds. Thinking that it is possible to design such a structure or even to
micromanage it with macroeconomic policy is a fatal conceit.
The division of
labor reflected by the capital structure is based on a division of knowledge.
Within and across firms specialized tasks are accomplished by those who know
best how to accomplish them. Such localized, often unconscious, knowledge could
not be communicated to or collected by centralized decision-makers. The market
process is responsible not only for discovering who should do what and how, but
also how to organize it so that those best able to make decisions are motivated
to do so. In other words, incentives and knowledge considerations tend to get
balanced spontaneously in a way that could not be planned on a grand scale. The
boundaries of firms expand and contract, and new forms of organization evolve.
This too is part of the capital structure broadly understood.
Division of Knowledge
In addition, the
heterogeneous capital goods that make up the cellular capital combinations also
reflect the division of knowledge. Capital goods (like specialized machines)
are employed because they “know” how to do certain important things; they
embody the knowledge of their designers about how to perform the tasks for
which they were designed. The entire production structure is thus based on an
incredibly intricate extended division of knowledge, such knowledge being
spread across its multiple physical and human capital components. Modern
production management is more than ever knowledge management, whether involving
human beings or machines—the key difference being that the latter can be owned
and require no incentives to motivate their production, while the former depend
on “relationships” but possess initiative and judgment in a way that machines
do not.
The foregoing
provides the barest account of the rich legacy of Austrian capital theory, but
it should be sufficient to communicate the essential differences between the
Austrian view of the economy and that of other schools of thought. For
Austrians the whole macroeconomic approach is problematic, involving, as it
does, the use of gross aggregrates as targets for policy
manipulation—aggregates like the economy’s “capital stock.” For Austrians there
is no “capital stock.” Any attempt to aggregate the multitude of diverse
capital items involved in production into a single number is bound to result in
a meaningless outcome: a number devoid of significance. Similarly the total of
investment spending does not reflect in any accurate way the addition to value
that can be produced by this “capital stock.” The values of capital goods and
of capital combinations, or of the businesses in which they are employed, are
determined only as the market process unfolds over time. They are based on the
expectations of the entrepreneurs who hire them, and these expectations are
diverse and often inconsistent. Not all of them will prove correct—indeed most
will be, at least to some degree, proven false. Basing macroeconomic policy on
an aggregate of values for assembled capital items as recorded or estimated at
one point in time would seem to be a fool’s errand. What do the policymakers
know that the entrepreneurs involved in the micro aspects of production do not?
Capital and Employment
The folly is
compounded by connecting capital and investment aggregates to total employment
under the assumption that stimulating the former will stimulate the latter.
Such an assumption ignores the heterogeneity and structural nature of both
capital and labor (human capital). Simply boosting expenditure on any kind of
production will not guarantee the employment of people without jobs. How else
to explain that our current economy is characterized by both sizeable
unemployment numbers and job vacancies? Their coexistence is a result of a
structural mismatch: The structure (that is, the pattern of skills) of the
unemployed does not match those required to be able to work with the specific
capital items that are currently unemployed.
In fact the
current enduring recession is basically structural in nature. It is the bust of
a credit-induced boom-bust cycle, augmented by far-reaching
production-distorting regulation. The Austrian theory of the business cycle was
developed first by Ludwig von Mises, combining insights from the Austrian theory
of capital with the nature of modern central-bank-led monetary policy. The
theory was later used, with some differences, by Hayek in his debates with
Keynes. Over the years its popularity and acceptance have waxed and waned, but
it appears to be highly relevant to our current situation.
Dot-Com and Other Bubbles
The dot-com boom
no doubt reflected the advent of a pervasive new technological environment: the
arrival and expansion of the digital age. It was a time of great promise and
uncertainty and of enhanced risk-taking. Astronomical book values reflected
expectations that in total could not be realized. A shakeup was inevitable—and
known to be so. It was part of the market process. As the boom expanded,
interest rates started to rise, reflecting the increased demand for a limited
supply of loanable funds. This, as Hayek would have put it, is the natural
brake of the economy, the signal and the incentive to slow down. But the
Federal Reserve, not wishing to spoil the party, expanded reserves to keep interest
rates low, thus allowing the boom to progress beyond its “natural” life. When
the bust came it was bigger than it would have been had the cycle been allowed
to run its natural course.
Notice how this
story accords with our understanding of the capital structure. The expanding
boom reflected entrepreneurs’ expectations of profitably making new capital
combinations, only some of which would, in the event, prove to be profitable.
But there was no way to know which they were ahead of time. That is why we need
markets. Rising interest rates and the passage of time would tend to reveal the
less viable ventures and weed them out. Keeping interest rates artificially low
prevented this from happening, more so for those projects that were more
interest-sensitive—namely, those that had a longer time horizon—or, loosely
speaking in terms of our earlier discussion, contained more “time.”
But the dot-com
collapse did not really mark the end of the cycle. Much of the extra liquidity
was then directed into real estate, specifically into residential housing and
into financial assets based on it. This investment channel was wide open as a
result of a decades-long, recently intensified congressional and regulatory
policy to expand homeownership in America. This is a familiar story that need
not be repeated here. The result was an unprecedented expansion of home
building and home purchases riding the tsunami wave of home prices. Once again
the production structure was pushed out of sync with any kind of sustainable
pattern of consumption.
The solution, from
this perspective, is to remove the distortions—to allow the market process to
“restructure” production. This would mean a sustained period of consolidation
in the housing market, not a policy that attempts to revive it (to revive the
bubble?) of the kind we are currently witnessing. But then today’s policymakers
do not have the benefit of knowing Austrian capital theory.
No comments:
Post a Comment