by Murray N. Rothbard
One of Ludwig von Mises's keenest insights was on the
cumulative tendency of government intervention. The government, in its wisdom,
perceives a problem (and Lord knows, there are always problems!). The
government then intervenes to "solve" that problem. But lo and
behold! instead of solving the initial problem, the intervention creates two or
three further problems, which the government feels it must intervene to heal,
and so on toward socialism.
No industry provides a more dramatic illustration of
this malignant process than medical care. We stand at the seemingly inexorable
brink of fully socialized medicine, or what is euphemistically called
"national health insurance." Physician and hospital prices are high
and are always rising rapidly, far beyond general inflation. As a result, the
medically uninsured can scarcely pay at all, so that those who are not
certifiable claimants for charity or Medicaid are bereft. Hence, the call for
national health insurance.
But why are rates high and increasing rapidly? The
answer is the very existence of healthcare insurance, which was established or
subsidized or promoted by the government to help ease the previous burden of
medical care. Medicare, Blue Cross, etc., are also very peculiar forms of
"insurance."
If your house burns down and you have fire insurance, you receive (if you can pry the money loose from your friendly insurance company) a compensating fixed money benefit. For this privilege, you pay in advance a fixed annual premium. Only in our system of medical insurance does the government or Blue Cross pay, not a fixed sum, but whatever the doctor or hospital chooses to charge.
In economic terms, this means that the demand curve
for physicians and hospitals can rise without limit. In short, in a form
grotesquely different from Say's Law, the suppliers can literally create their
own demand through unlimited third-party payments to pick up the tab. If demand
curves rise virtually without limit, so too do the prices of the service.
In order to stanch the flow of taxes or subsidies, in recent years the government and other third-party insurers have felt obliged to restrict somewhat the flow of goodies: by increasing deductibles, or by putting caps on Medicare payments. All this has been met by howls of anguish from medical customers who have come to think of unlimited third-party payments as some sort of divine right, and from physicians and hospitals who charge the government with "socialistic price controls" — for trying to stem its own largesse to the healthcare industry!
In addition to artificial raising of the demand curve,
there is another deep flaw in the medical-insurance concept. Theft is theft,
and fire is fire, so that fire or theft insurance is fairly clear-cut — the
only problem being the "moral hazard" of insurees succumbing to the
temptation of burning down their own unprofitable store or apartment house, or
staging a fake theft, in order to collect the insurance.
"Medical care," however, is a vague and
slippery concept. There is no way by which it can be measured or gauged or even
defined. A "visit to a physician" can range all the way from a
careful and lengthy investigation and discussion, and thoughtful advice, to a
two-minute run-through with the doctor doing not much else than advising two
aspirin and having the nurse write out the bill.
Moreover, there is no way to prevent a galloping moral
hazard, as customers — their medical bills reduced to near-zero — decide to go
to the doctor every week to have their blood pressure checked or their
temperature taken. Hence, it is impossible, under third-party insurance, to
prevent a gross decline in the quality of medical care, along with a severe
shortage of the supply of such care in relation to the swelling demand.
Everyone old enough to remember the good old days of
family physicians making house calls, spending a great deal of time with and
getting to know the patient, and charging low fees to boot, is deeply and
properly resentful of the current assembly-line care. But all too few
understand the role of the much-beloved medical insurance itself in bringing
about this sorry decline in quality, as well as the astronomical rise in
prices.
But the roots of the current medical crisis go back
much further than the 1950s and medical insurance. Government intervention into
medicine began much earlier, with a watershed in 1910 when the much-celebrated
Flexner Report changed the face of American medicine.
Abraham Flexner, an unemployed former owner of a prep
school in Kentucky, and sporting neither a medical degree nor any other
advanced degree, was commissioned by the Carnegie Foundation to write a study
of American medical education. Flexner's only qualification for this job was to
be the brother of the powerful Dr. Simon Flexner, indeed a physician and head
of the Rockefeller Institute for Medical Research. Flexner's report was
virtually written in advance by high officials of the American Medical
Association, and its advice was quickly taken by every state in the Union.
The result: every medical school and hospital was
subjected to licensing by the state, which would turn the power to appoint
licensing boards over to the state AMA. The state was supposed to, and did, put
out of business all medical schools that were proprietary and profit-making,
that admitted blacks and women, and that did not specialize in orthodox,
"allopathic" medicine: particularly homeopaths, who were then a
substantial part of the medical profession, and a respectable alternative to
orthodox allopathy.
Thus through the Flexner Report, the AMA was able to
use government to cartelize the medical profession: to push the supply curve
drastically to the left (literally half the medical schools in the country were
put out of business by post-Flexner state governments), and thereby to raise
medical and hospital prices and doctors' incomes.
In all cases of cartels, the producers are able to
replace consumers in their seats of power, and accordingly the medical
establishment was now able to put competing therapies (e.g., homeopathy) out of
business; to remove disliked competing groups from the supply of physicians
(blacks, women, Jews); and to replace proprietary medical schools financed by
student fees with university-based schools run by the faculty, and subsidized
by foundations and wealthy donors.
When managers such as trustees take over from owners
financed by customers (students of patients), the managers become governed by
the perks they can achieve rather than by service of consumers. Hence: a
skewing of the entire medical profession away from patient care to toward
high-tech, high-capital investment in rare and glamorous diseases, which
rebound far more to the prestige of the hospital and its medical staff than it
is actually useful for the patient-consumers.
And so, our very real medical crisis has been the
product of massive government intervention, state and federal, throughout the
century; in particular, an artificial boosting of demand coupled with an
artificial restriction of supply. The result has been accelerating high prices
and deterioration of patient care. And next, socialized medicine could easily
bring us to the vaunted medical status of the Soviet Union: everyone has the
right to free medical care, but there is, in effect, no medicine and no care.
No comments:
Post a Comment