By Anthony de Jasay
Having
for a pulpit a regular column in the New York Times, Paul
Krugman speaks to us as one who is really sure about what is what. He is also
thoroughly exasperated by the pigheaded blindness of those of us who have their
hands on the levers of policy and are responsible for the astronomical waste
and needless pain inflicted on the economies on both sides of the Atlantic and
especially on the Eurozone. His thesis is that we are actually in a state of
genuine depression, involving a loss of potential output that hardly bears
thinking about. The depression is of our own making and is unnecessary, serving
no purpose. It ought to be and could be terminated forthwith.
Its cause is the misguided attempt by the majority of Eurozone states to tackle their indebtedness by reducing the rate at which it has been increasing as a proportion of GDP for the last two or three decades. For the average Eurozone state, this proportion rose from 30 to 90 per cent of GDP. It is now rising each year at 3.5 or 4 percentage points for Italy and France and at 8 percentage points for Spain—to speak only of the countries that are not on intensive care like Greece, Portugal and Ireland, nor in reasonable health like the Teutonic group. All 17 states signed up to the Golden Rule that would limit their "structural" budget deficit to 0.5 per cent of GDP, but it is far from evident that all will succeed or even genuinely try, to achieve this in the foreseeable future. The agreement they signed, though not yet ratified, provides for "sanctions" by the European Court of Justice, but serious sanctions cannot realistically be applied. Meanwhile, the order of the day is austerity, mostly by cutting expenditure as in Spain, increasing taxation as in France, and curbing tax evasion as in Italy.
Many economists, with Paul Krugman and George Stiglitz in the lead, argue that dealing with indebtedness by austerity, though a commonsense remedy for a household, is self-defeating at the level of an entire economy, for austerity stifles economic growth, hence it reduces tax revenues and worsens the budget deficit that the austerity was meant to improve. The argument is enthusiastically seconded by politicians who expect to win votes by promising maintained or increased government spending on welfare, subsidies and other popular items, some of which may even have genuine merit, but cannot be afforded.
Krugman's mantra is "my
spending is your income". If I spend more, your income rises, hence you
spend more and the money I have spent comes back to me. We are both better off.
It is simply foolish not to see that this is the obvious and wide open way out
of the depression that austerity has brought about.
Austerity, to be sure,
operates by a variety of measures, some of which are dictated by the laws of
least resistance and are inefficient or harmful. They are biased to raising
taxation rather than reducing spending, and also to multiplying the bewildering
tangle of regulatory and fiscal interventions, each of which designed to serve
some good purpose but whose aggregate is oppressive and strangles the normally
expansionary impulse in the economy. How good an alternative is the Krugman
way?
The "my spending is your
income" mantra is true enough in a closed economy, but false in an open
one. You may not spend the income you receive from me on what I have for sale,
but rather on what a Taiwanese manufacturer of electronic gadgets has for sale.
Your extra income does not flow back to me, but "leaks" into inputs.
It is not surprising, then, that Krugmanites often show some more or less
disguised sympathy for protectionism in some fig-leafed-covered form. Worse
than the leakage into imports is the effect on both the willingness to invest
and consumer confidence. David Ricardo saw that government debt
depressed private demand as business and consumers take account of the future
taxes they will be made to pay to service the debt. A similar but wider effect
of increasing government debt is that it brings closer the day when the threat
of sovereign default simply forces the adoption of the most cruel austerity. It
is as if the Keynesian multiplier took on a negative value, decreasing
aggregate demand when government dissaves and increasing it when government
saves.
Consider a scenario where
three not-so-solid Eurozone countries, France, Italy and Spain decide to take
the Krugman way out of the stagnant or gently declining economic conditions the
present austerity creates for them. Tentatively, though with limited
confidence, we may suppose that if they open the valves of government spending
their annual deficit rises to 7 per cent of GDP for France and Italy and 9 per
cent of GDP for Spain; that this deficit is maintained for three years; and
that at the end of this period, the economies of these countries enter into
such a growth phase that they can without austerity obey the Golden Rule and
run a balanced budget. (Ignore the strong likelihood that in a democracy, a
balanced budget would provoke a pressing demand for more welfare, more
subsidies and lower taxes that the government would find electorally impossible
to resist). Under this assumptions, by the time reasonable growth began, the
proportion of debt to GDP of the three countries would be roughly 22 to 28
percentage points higher than at the outset. At unchanged interest rates, the
service charge on the national debt could require an extra 1 to 1.5 per cent of
GDP forever after, a handicap whose weight looks easy when seen from afar but a
heavy servitude when it is borne year after year.
This handicap may perhaps be
brushed aside as bearable. There is, however, a far more disturbing implication
of the putative return to growth via higher government spending. In fact, apart
from the assumption that it lifts the economy out of depression, it is impossible
to tell where the Krugman way would lead it. One possible arrival point would
be highly dangerous. Uplift by easy government spending and easy times would
leave these economies as inefficient and inflexible at the end of three years
as they were at the outset. However, growing at 2.5 per cent they would
certainly import more and may well export less than at a growth rate of 0 or
0.5. Their current balance of payments, already negative, could become
dramatically weak. The semi-permanent sovereign debt "crisis" they
now live with would become a mother of all balance of payments crisis. There
are currently persistent demands for Germany to take on the sovereign debt
crisis on the transparent pretext that as separate national currencies have been
replaced by the euro, separate national debt obligations must now be replaced
by a mutual common obligation, the Eurobond. Germany has up to now declined the
honour of supporting a Eurobond, and is very unlikely to accept the honour of
supporting the Latin countries' balance of payments deficits. One alternative
is the breakup of the euro, a reversion to the franc, the lira, and the peseta
and a mother of all devaluations until the Mediterranean countries become more
competitive at the cost of worse terms of trade. Where else the Krugman way may
lead is a puzzle.
The alternative to
spend-and-borrow is austerity. It takes two forms:
spend-less-and-maintain-taxes, or raise-taxes-but-maintain-spending.
State-of-the-art economic research as well as the OECD and the IMF have no
hesitation to say that reducing public spending is the more effective form of
austerity. Indeed, when 57 per cent of national output, produced by
individuals, is pre-empted and disposed of by collective choice, as is the case
in France, the holder of the world record in the matter, it is hard to say how
maintained collective spending (central and local government and compulsory old
age, health and unemployment insurance ) could be a viable solution.
However, the political odds
are against less spending. Keeping expenditure high and raising taxation higher
is the odds-on favourite in democratic states. The reason is that electoral
majorities punish governments more severely for reducing public services and
nominal incomes than for raising taxes. In fact, taxing the "rich"
and "privileged" and also banking and oil, is positively welcomed by
majorities. Taxing the poor by consumption taxes is electorally quite well
tolerated, and it is this that brings the big money into the state coffers.
The typical upshot of adopting
austerity in order to bring deficits under control is politically easier but
economically not very suitable.
What are the chances then, of
a regime of austerity bringing about, not only a better budget and external
payments balance, but also an economic system which is allowed to breathe more
freely and which regains its underlying tendency to grow (if it were not kept
down by the twin burden of the public sector and excessive regulation)?
It does not flatter us and our
manner of government, but seems nonetheless the case that the only time a
majority will forget its short-term urges and allows realistic long-term
objectives to prevail, is when it is driven by fear. It was a scared electorate
that mandated Margaret Thatcher in Britain in 1979 and Ronald Reagan in the
United States in 1980 to try to reverse the decline of these countries. There
is some hope that if today opinion-makers in Europe look at Greece and say
"there, but for the grace of God, go we", intelligent governments may
be allowed to reform some of the perverse structures and dismantle to obstacles
that contort the economy. Burning all but a few of the 3,000 pages of a code of
labour law would do wonders for job creation at the expense of job protection.
It would be ironical but poetic justice if, by a desperate but bold change of
course, austerity would finally bring back more prosperity for all in a more
liberal order that majorities love to hate and vilify.
No comments:
Post a Comment