The core of the
argument is this: Every classic account surplus country, with a permanent
preponderance of exports against imports, constantly accumulates money claims
on foreign countries. But loans to foreign buyers of German goods are never
fully repaid; they are always written down, extended or rescheduled.
This means that
the real net foreign assets of a surplus state like Germany is always well
below the cumulative total of past current account surpluses. Within a monetary
union, where the normal safety valve to reduce external imbalances through
currency realignments no longer exists, the problem is particularly acute.
But sooner or
later, one way or the other, the problem is solved. Theoretically, resolution
could come by Germany running a high inflation rate, becoming uncompetitive,
and running down its foreign assets through a string of current account
deficits.
Alternatively, the
deficit countries (or Germany itself) could leave EMU (ICAPC:EURUSD) . If we reject these two options, then
the only way out is through lenders writing off loans and debtors stretching
out redemptions.
The story of the
rise and fall of Germany’s net foreign assets before and after monetary union
illustrates these basic trends.
In the years
before the reunification in 1990, West Germany accumulated net foreign assets
in the amount of 500 billion deutsche marks (€250 billion). A considerable sum,
inherited from years of strong exports. Yet the number never grew
astronomically, because extreme current account imbalances in Europe were
avoided by repeated realignments within the European Monetary System.
Around 1990,
Bundesbank President Hans Tietmeyer farsightedly predicted that West Germany’s
net foreign assets would act as a “reserve army” to absorb the costs of
unification. A forecast that proved true, because in the years leading up to
the introduction of the euro the net pile of cash and capital almost completely
disappeared as a result of post-unity tensions in the German economy,
manifested in several years of current account deficits.
Germany thus at
the beginning of 1999 entered EMU with hardly any net foreign assets (according
to Bundesbank statistics: 34 million euros). Since then, due to the well-known
shifts in competitiveness of individual euro member states and the consequent
large current account imbalances, Germany’s net foreign assets have risen
sharply, topping the 1,000 billion euro level in March 2012, four times as high
as the 1990 figure.
This is the high
summit from the Federal Republic will now have to descend.
From now on,
quietly but inexorably, Germany will have to dig into its net foreign assets
total, even if the German current account surplus continues for a few years at
a relatively high level. Transfer payments to, and debt reduction measures by,
the southern euro members can take us in only one direction. Some will call
this a “transfer union”. Others will say it’s a clever adaptation to reality.
Either way,
Germany will be poorer, in terms of its net foreign assets, in 10 years than it
is today – as part of the price for keeping EMU.
This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDelete