The Cypriot
banking system is insolvent; it needs a large capital injection. As in several
other peripheral states of the Eurozone, Cyprus cannot resolve the crisis
alone. Given an already high debt-to-GDP ratio and an oversized banking system,
recapitalising the banks via sovereign debt would produce unsustainable
sovereign-debt levels and, ultimately, sovereign default. In short, Cyprus’s
banks are too big to fail, and too big to save.
This is why
Cyprus negotiated a rescue package with the Troika – ECB, European Commission
and IMF. The ‘bailout’ agreement (in quotation marks, as it is not quite sure
who is supposed to be bailed out here, certainly not Cypriot taxpayers and
their children, to be burdened with debt for a long time) is still in the
making and might even fall through. The damage, however, has already been
done. There has been a complete loss of confidence, not only in the Cypriot
banking system but also in the crisis-management capacity of the Eurozone.
The Saturday morning hangover
The decision
taken in the early hours of last Saturday caused indignation and rejection
across Europe, and rightly so. While imposing market discipline is a useful
aim, and long overdue after four years of bailouts at the expense of taxpayers
and future generations, the way it was originally to be imposed in the case of
Cyprus has been more than counter-productive.
Economists and
practitioners alike point to a couple of common principles in bank resolution. One is respect for creditor ranking:
· Equity holders take a hit before junior debt holders;
· Junior debt holders take a hit before senior creditors and uninsured depositors.
· Insured depositors should take a hit last.
Such a creditor
ranking is based not only on legal rules, but also on the idea that claims
should be priced according to their risk and expected repayment in case of
failure.
The ‘bailout’
deal with Cyprus foresees, however, a tax on deposits, originally imposed on
all deposits even those covered by the EU-wide deposit insurance. Put
differently, insured depositors suffer a haircut, while uninsured depositors
still maintain a large share of their claims. This seems a violation of the
creditor ranking, in spirit if not in the letter of the law.
In order to not
violate the promise of deposit insurance of up to 100,000 euros, what the
agreement calls a tax is effectively an insurance co-payment. There is nothing
to be said against co-insurance, which can improve market discipline, but
introducing it ex-post constitutes a clear violation of trust. And if it walks
like a duck and it quacks like a duck, let’s call it a duck! This is not a tax,
but an ex-post insurance co-payment and loss-sharing arrangement.
But there is
more. Imposing losses on depositors is to be done in order to reduce the risk
of sovereign over-indebtedness and thus guarantee repayment of current
sovereign-bond holders. Imposing losses on insured bank depositors to thus
guarantee repayments to sovereign-bond holders violates another political
priority of putting (certainly more sophisticated) bond holders above (mostly
less sophisticated) holders of small deposits.
Finally,
imposing a tax on depositors of all banks, independent of the financial
situation of each bank, further undermines market discipline. Yes, it seems an
easier option, requiring less administrative effort, but it sends the message
that investors do not have to price investments properly as the haircut is the
same across banks. And it increases herding trends towards aggressive
risk-taking.
Addressing the problem at its core
The Cypriot
economy is in crisis, for many reasons. But the insolvency of the banking
system is at the core of the current crisis, and should therefore be the focus
of the resolution. The literature on resolving bank crises has pointed to
several important lessons. On is that losses should be recognised early on,
allocated and then managed. While the flow solution, i.e. re-establishing
solvency of the banking system through retained earnings or future government
earnings, seems attractive as it avoids immediate pain, it comes at high risks.
Financing
recapitalisation out of future taxes and expected privatisation gains is also
counterproductive as it ties banks and governments together yet again. Fiscal
tightening will lead to an increase in non-performing assets in the banking
system. Unless banks are properly recapitalised, they will not be able to
support the private sector and the economy in its attempt to grow out of the
crisis, which in turn undermines government finances.
Finally, tying
banks and governments together creates expectations that more adjustments and
possible write-downs might be ahead. There is a tendency in such circumstances
to under-estimate losses and overestimate future revenues, as the Greek case
has clearly shown.
As so often
before, the ‘bailout’ agreement has caused more trouble than solved problems.
Rather than disentangling banking and sovereign-debt crisis, it has tied them
again together, by shifting bank insolvency to sovereign-debt insolvency.
Hello Iceland!
Iceland was
vilified in 2008 for allowing its banks to fail, transferring domestic deposits
into good banks and leaving foreign deposits and other claims and bad assets in
the original banks, to be resolved over time. On the other hand, the Icelandic
government kept its fiscal house in order and maintained an investment grade
for its bonds throughout the crisis. Iceland’s economy has recovered building
on industries other than banks for renewed growth, even though Iceland’s
society is still suffering from the traumatic events of 2008. And while
mistakes might have been in the resolution process (Danielsson, 2011),
Iceland’s banking sector does not drag down Iceland’s growth any longer and
might eventually even make a positive contribution.
What can we
learn from Iceland? Unlike Cyprus it is outside the Eurozone, so it was
politically and legally easier for it to allow its banks to fail. The bank
failures, however, had ripple effects throughout the globe given the rapid
international expansion of Icelandic banks both in deposit collection and asset
markets. Such ripple effects might be actually lower in the case of a systemic
Cypriotic bank failure. Most importantly, Iceland’s experience ‘ended in
horror’ rather than led to the ‘horror without end’ that Greece has been living
through over the past four years and that Cyprus is now facing for years to
come. The Icelandic approach of recognising losses, allocating them and moving
on might not be easily replicable, but it certainly shows that there is an
alternative to the approach that the Eurozone has been taking over the past
four years! And as I will argue below, probably the only solution for Cyprus at
this late stage of the game.
Quo vadis, banking union?
The Cypriot
crisis has revived the Eurozone crisis, though many observers doubted that it
had ever gone quiet. And it
resurrects questions about:
·
What would have been different under a functioning banking union and;
·
What this crisis means for the future of the banking union.
The Cypriot
crisis has underlined again the urgent need for a Eurozone-wide approach to
bank resolution. It also underlines, however, that simply supervising banks on
the Eurozone level is not sufficient.
The gaps in
Cypriot banks’ balance sheets have been known for a long time (even if probably
not in its whole extent), but it is the resolution of these banks and the
funding of the resolution that is critical and goes beyond the capacity of the
Cypriot government. And even though the solvency gap has been known for a long
time, forbearance on the national level (linked to the political situation) has
made a bad situation worse.
But there is no banking union in place.
But there is no banking union in place.
·
‘Bailing out’ Cypriot banks with loans from the ESM is not an option as
this will turn the debt-to-GDP ratio in Cyprus unsustainable.
So, what else?
·
The only way seems to be a recapitalisation of Cypriot banks directly by
the ESM.
·
This is tough since there is no appetite in northern Europe to pour money
into the oversized Cypriot banking system.
·
This reinforces the call for a European Resolution Agency to take over
these banks, wipe out equity holders claims and recapitalise them, with profits
eventually going back to the ESM.
Looking at the
issue from a different perspective, the Cypriot crisis has shown that the
resolution of the current Eurozone crisis cannot wait and should not depend on
the construction of the banking union.
To construct a
functioning banking union, without which the Eurozone is not a sustainable
currency union, is a longer-term process. The crisis in Cyprus cannot wait for
the banking union. As suggested in a previous column (Beck, Gros and
Schoenmaker, 2013), the current crisis calls for the establishment of an asset-management
company or European Recapitalisation Agency, which would sort out fragile banks
across Europe, both small and large, with strongly capitalised banks allowed to
go ahead and weak banks either being recapitalised or (partly) liquidated.
Where possible, banks should be recapitalised through the market; if not
feasible, the resolution authority recapitalises by taking an equity stake in
the bank (by straight equity or hybrid securities).
And the politics …
A lot has been
written about the bad idea of forcing losses upon insured depositors (Wyplosz
2013 ). But there is an increasingly clear picture that it might not have been
creditor countries or the Troika who came up with this idea, but maybe the
Cypriot government itself in order to avoid imposing losses on large (and thus
most likely) richer and more connected depositors. Which is yet another
indication of how closely politics and finance can be interconnected, with
strong though opaque lobbying power of the oversized banking industry.
The failure of
the Cypriot banking system also shows yet again the risks of financial centres
in small economies, i.e. the idea of the financial sector as an export sector,
i.e. one that seeks to build a nationally centred financial-centre stronghold
based on relative comparative advantages such as skill base, favourable
regulatory policies, subsidies, etc. As recent research (Beck, Degryse and
Kneer 2013) has shown, a large financial system might stimulate growth in the
short term, but comes at the expense of higher volatility. It is the
financial-intermediation function of finance that helps improve growth
prospects, not a large financial centre, a lesson that Cyprus could have
learned from Iceland.
Looking forward
Cypriot banks
urgently need restructuring, but so does its economy more generally. The
economic model based on an oversized financial centre has failed, but a
functioning financial system is necessary to handle its economic transformation
to a new model.
·
Splitting the Cypriot banking system into a bad ‘legacy’ part and a good
forward-looking part seems the only feasible and effective solution to resolve
the current crisis and restore trust.
It is not an
easy solution, but certainly more promising than the proposals being discussed
in Nicosia and Brussels, which will just extend misery and deepen the crisis
further.
If Europe is to
help, it should be by helping to resolve a broken banking system, not just by
providing resources but by actively helping in the resolution process. Doing so
would be a true signal of European solidarity and a first step out of the
Eurozone crisis.
References
Beck, Thorsten,
Daniel Gros, Dirk Schoenmaker (2012), “Banking union instead of Eurobonds – disentangling
sovereign and banking crises“, VoxEU.org, 24
June.
Beck, Thorsten,
Hans Degryse and Christiane Kneer (2013), “Is More Finance Better?
Disentangling Intermediation and Size Effects of Financial Systems”, Journal
of Financial Stability, forthcoming.
Danielsson, Jon
(2011), “How not to resolve a banking crisis: Learning from
Iceland’s mistakes“, VoxEU.org, 26 November.
Wyplosz, Charles
(2013), “Cyprus: The next blunder“, VoxEU.org, 18
March.
No comments:
Post a Comment