Reinhart,
Rogoff Strike Back At "Hyperbolic" Krugman
Dear Paul
Back in the late 1980s, you helped shape the concept of an emerging market debt overhang. The
financial crisis has laid bare the fact that the dividing line between emerging
markets and advanced countries is not as crisp as once thought. Indeed,
this is a recurring theme of our 2009 book, This Time is Different:
Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Today, the growth bind of
advanced countries in the periphery of the eurozone has a great deal in common
with that of emerging market economies of the 1980s.
We admire your past scholarly work, which influences us to this day.
So it has been with deep disappointment that we have experienced your
spectacularly uncivil behavior the past few weeks. You have attacked us
in very personal terms, virtually non-stop, in your New York Times column and blog posts. Now
you have doubled down in the New York Review of
Books, adding the accusation we didn't share our data. Your
characterization of our work and of our policy impact is selective and
shallow. It is deeply misleading about where we stand on the
issues. And we would respectfully submit, your logic and evidence on the
policy substance is not nearly as compelling as you imply.
You particularly take aim at our 2010 paper on the long-term secular
association between high debt and slow growth. That you disagree with our
interpretation of the results is your prerogative. Your thoroughly
ignoring the subsequent literature, however, including the International
Monetary Fund's work as well as our own deeper and more complete 2012 paper with
Vincent Reinhart, is troubling. Perhaps, acknowledging the updated
literature-not to mention decades of theoretical, empirical, and historical
contributions on drawbacks to high debt-would inconveniently undermine your
attempt to make us a scapegoat for austerity. You write
"Indeed, Reinhart-Rogoff may have had more immediate influence on public debate than any previous paper in the history of economics."
"Indeed, Reinhart-Rogoff may have had more immediate influence on public debate than any previous paper in the history of economics."
Setting aside this wild hyperbole, you never seem to mention our other line
of work that has surely been far more influential when it comes to responding
to the financial crisis. Specifically, our 2009 book (released before our
growth and debt work) showed that recoveries from deep systemic financial
crises are long, slow and painful. This was not the common wisdom at all
before us, as you yourself have
acknowledged on more than one occasion. Over the course of the crisis, and
certainly by 2010, policymakers around the world were using our research,
alongside their assessments, to help justify sustained macroeconomic easing of
both monetary and fiscal policy fronts.
Your desire to blame our later 2010 paper for the stances of some
politicians fails to recognize a basic reality: We were out there
endorsing very different policies. Anyone with experience in these
matters knows that politicians may float a citation to an academic paper if it
suits their purposes. But there are limits to how much policy traction they
can get with this device when the paper's authors are out offering very
different policy conclusions. You can refer to the appendix to this
letter for our views on policy through the financial crisis as they were stated
publicly in real time. We were not silent.
Very senior former policy makers, observing the attacks of the past few
weeks, have forcefully explained that real-time policies are very seldom driven
to any significant extent by a single academic paper or result.
It is worth noting that in the past, polemicists have often pinned the
austerity charge on the International Monetary Fund for its work with countries
having temporary or permanent debt sustainability issues. Since its
origins after World War II, IMF programs have almost always involved some
combination of austerity, debt restructurings, and structural reform.
When a country that has been running large deficits is suddenly no longer able
to borrow new funds, some measure of adjustment is invariably required, and one
of the IMF's usual roles has been to serve as a lightning rod. Even
before the IMF existed, long periods of autarky and hardship accompanied debt
crises.
Now let us turn to the substance. The events of the past few weeks do not
change basic facts and fundamentals.
Some Fundamentals on Debt
First, the advanced economies now have levels of
debt that surpass most if not all historic episodes. It is public debt and
private debt (which often becomes public as a crisis unfolds). Significant
shares of these debts are held by foreigners in most cases, with the notable
exception of Japan. In Europe, where the (public and private) external
debt exposures loom largest, financial de-globalization is well underway.
Debt financing has become an increasingly domestic business and a difficult one
when the pool of domestic saving is limited.
As for the United States: our only short-lived high-debt episode involved
WWII debts, which were held by domestic residents, not fickle international
investors or central banks in China and elsewhere around the globe. This
observation is not meant to suggest "a scare" in the offing, with
bond vigilantes driving a concerted sell-off of Treasuries by the rest of the
world and a dramatic spike US in interest rates. Carmen's work on
financial repression suggests a different scenario. But many emerging markets
have stepped into bubble-like territory and we have seen this movie
before. We should not take for granted their prosperity that makes
possible their continuing large-scale purchases of US debt. Reversals are
possible. Sensible risk management means planning for these and other
contingencies that might disturb today's low global interest rate environment.
Second, on debt and growth. The Herndon, Ash
and Pollin paper, using a different methodology, reinforces our core result
that high levels of debt are associated with lower growth. This fact has
been hidden in the tabloid media and blogosphere discourse, but this point is
made plain by even a cursory look at the full set of results reported in the
very paper they critique. More importantly, the result was prominently
featured in our 2012 Journal of Economic Perspectives paper with
Vincent Reinhart on Debt Overhangs, which they do not cite. The main point of
our 2012 paper is that while the difference in annual GDP growth between high
and lower debt cases is about one percent a year, debt overhang episodes last
on average 23 years. Thus, the cumulative effect on income levels over time is
significant.
Third, the debate of the last few weeks does not
change the fact that debt levels above 90% (even if one entirely rejects this
marker for gross central government debt as a common cross-country
"threshold") are very rare altogether and even rarer in
peacetime. From 1955 until right before the recent crisis, advanced
economies spent less than 10% of those years at a debt/GDP ratio of higher than
90%; only about two percent of the years are above 120% debt/GDP. If governments
thought high debt was a riskless proposition, why did they avoid it so
consistently?
Debt and Growth Causality
Your recent April 29, 2013 NY Times blog The Italian Miracle is meant
to highlight how in high-debt Italy, interest rates have come down since the
European Central Bank's well-placed efforts to act more as a lender of last
resort to periphery countries. No disagreement there. However, this
positive development is meant to re-enforce your strongly held view that high
debt is not a problem (even for Italy) and that causality runs exclusively from
slow growth to debt. You do not mention that in this miracle economy, GDP
fell by more than 2 percent in 2012 and is expected to fall by a similar amount
this year. Elsewhere you have stated that you are sure that Italy's long-term
secular growth/debt problems, which date back to the 1990s, are purely a case
of slow growth causing high debt. This claim is highly debatable.
Indeed, your repeatedly-expressed view that slow growth causes high debt
but not visa-versa, is hardly supported by the recent literature on the
subject. Of course, as we have already noted, this work has been
singularly ignored in the public discourse of the past few weeks. The
best and worst that can be said is that the results are mixed. A number
of studies looking at more comprehensive growth models have found significant
effects of debt on growth. We made this point in the appendix to our New
York Times piece. Of course, it is well known that the economic cycle
impacts government finances and therefore debt (causation from growth to debt).
Cyclically adjusted budgets have been around for decades, your shallow
characterization of the growth-debt connection.
As for ways debt might affect growth, there is debt with drama and debt
without drama.
Debt with drama. Do you
really think that a country that is suddenly unable to borrow from
international capital markets because its public and/or private debts that are
a contingent public liability are deemed unsustainable will not suffer lower
growth and higher unemployment as a consequence? With governments and banks
shut out from international capital markets, credit to firms and households in
periphery Europe remains paralyzed. This credit crunch has a crippling effect
on growth and employment with or without austerity. Fiscal austerity reinforces
the procyclicality of the external and domestic credit crunch. This
pattern is not unique to this episode.
Policy response to debt with drama. On the policy
response to this sad state of affairs, we stress that restoring the credit
channel is essential for sustained growth, and this is why there is a need to
write off senior bank debt in many countries. Furthermore, there is no reason
why the ECB should buy only sovereign debt-purchases of senior bank debt along
the lines of the US Federal Reserve's purchases of mortgage-backed securities
would be instrumental in rekindling credit and working capital for firms.
We don't see your attraction to fiscal largesse as a substitute. Periphery
Europe cannot afford it and for Germany, which can afford it, fiscal expansion
would be procyclical. Any overheating in Germany would exert pressure on
the ECB to maintain a tighter monetary policy, backtracking some of the
progress made by Mario Draghi. A better use of Germany's balance sheet strength
would be to agree on faster and bigger haircuts for the periphery, and to
support significantly more expansionary monetary policy by the ECB.
Debt without drama. There are other
cases, like the US today or Japan since the mid-1990s, where there is debt
without drama. The plain fact that we know less about these episodes is a
point we already made in our New York Times piece.
We pointedly do not include the historical episodes of 19th century
UK and Netherlands among these puzzling cases. Those imperial debts were
importantly financed by massive resource transfers from the colonies. They had
"good" high-debt centuries because their colonies did not. We
offer a number of ideas in our 2012 paper for why debt overhang might matter
even when there is no imminent collapse of borrowing capacity.
Bad shocks do happen. What is the foundation for your certainty that as
peacetime debt hits new records in coming years, the United States will be able
to engage in forceful countercyclical fiscal policy if hit by a large
unexpected shock? Furthermore, do you really want to find out the answer
to that question the hard way?
The United Kingdom, which does not issue a reserve currency, is more
dependent on its financial sector and suffered a bigger banking bust, has not
had the same shale gas revolution, and is more vulnerable to Europe, is clearly
more exposed to the drama scenario than the US. And yet you regularly
assert that the situations in the US and UK are the same and that both
countries have the costless option of engaging in an open-ended fiscal
expansion. Of course, this does not preclude high-return infrastructure
investments, making use of the public balance sheet directly or indirectly through
public-private partnerships.
Policy response to debt without drama. Let us be clear,
we have addressed the role of somewhat higher inflation and financial
repression in debt reduction in our research and in numerous pieces of
commentary. As our appendix shows, we did not advocate austerity in the
immediate wake of the crisis when recovery was frail. But the subprime
crisis began in the summer of 2007, now six years ago. Waiting 10 to 15 more years to deal
with a festering problem is an invitation for decay, if not necessarily an
outright debt crisis. The end may not come with a bang but with a
whimper.
Scholarship: Stick to the facts
The accusation in the New York Review of Books is
a sloppy neglect on your part to check the facts before charging us with a
serious academic ethical infraction. You had already implicitly endorsed
this from your perch at the New York Times by
posting a link to a
program that treated the misstatement as fact.
Fortunately, the "Wayback Machine" crawls the Internet and
periodically makes wholesale copies of web pages. The debt/GDP database was
first archived in October 2010 from Carmen's
University of Maryland webpage. The data migrated to ReinhartandRogoff.com in March
2011. There it sits with our other data, on inflation, crises dates, and
exchange rates. These data are regularly sought and found for those doing
research who care to look. The greater disclosure of debt data from official
institutions is testament to this. The IMF began to construct historical
public debt data only after we had provided a roadmap in the list of our
detailed references in a 2009 book (and before that in a 2008 working paper) that explained
how we had unearthed the data.
Our interaction with scholars and practitioners working on real world
questions in our field is ongoing, and our doors remain open. So to accuse us
of not sharing our data is an unfounded attack on our academic and personal
integrity.
Recap
Finally, we attach, as do many other mainstream economists, a somewhat
higher weight on risks than you do, as debts of all measure -- including old
age liabilities, public debt, private debt and external debt -- ascend into
record territory. This is not a conclusion based on one or two
papers as you sometimes seem to imply, but rather on a long-standing body of
economic research and extensive historical experience about the risks of record
high debt levels.
You often cite John Maynard Keynes. We read Keynes, all the way
through. He wrote How to Pay for the War in
1940 precisely because he was not blasé about large deficits - even in support
of a cause as noble as a war of survival. Debt is a slow-moving variable that
cannot - and in general should not - be brought down too quickly. But
interest rates can change much more quickly than fiscal policy and debt.
You might be right, and this time might be, after all, different. If
so, we will admit that we were wrong. Whatever the outcome, we intend to
be there to put the results in proper context for the community of scholars,
policymakers, and civil society.
Respectfully yours,
Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff
Harvard University.
Appendix I. Reinhart and Rogoff: Selected interviews,
op-eds, and media on the policy response to crisis
"Two prominent economists who published an acclaimed study last
year of 800 years of national financial crises, "This Time Is
Different," see flaws on both sides of today's argument. The debt must be
dealt with, they say, but not too fast."
Paul Krugman, New
York Times, August 18, 2010 (Citing
from McClatchy article) "Rogoff: We may need another stimulus bill just to decompress
from the previous one, a smaller one to cushion the landing.
Reinhart: I'm not one of those deficit hawks.... I'm not saying you run
out and pull the plug and have an adjustment that could derail what fragile
recovery we do have. Good for them."
Top Culprit in the
Financial Crisis: Human Nature, Barrons, November 24, 2012, by Lawrence C. Strauss
Reinhart: "...the thrust in a deep financial crisis, when you throw in both monetary and fiscal stimulus, is to come up with something that helps raise the floor. That's why the decline wasn't 10% or 12%. However, one area where policy really has left a bit to be desired is that both in the U.S. and in Europe, we have embraced forbearance. Delaying debt write-downs and delaying marking to market is not particularly conducive to speeding up deleveraging and recovery."
Rogoff: "...if you didn't just raise taxes or cut taxes but actually fixed the tax system, that would be very important....And, lastly, other things, like infrastructure and education spending, are important. This isn't all about austerity versus no austerity. Countries that are successful in dealing with these crises, such as Sweden, sometimes take them as an opportunity to change. We haven't."
Reinhart: "...the thrust in a deep financial crisis, when you throw in both monetary and fiscal stimulus, is to come up with something that helps raise the floor. That's why the decline wasn't 10% or 12%. However, one area where policy really has left a bit to be desired is that both in the U.S. and in Europe, we have embraced forbearance. Delaying debt write-downs and delaying marking to market is not particularly conducive to speeding up deleveraging and recovery."
Rogoff: "...if you didn't just raise taxes or cut taxes but actually fixed the tax system, that would be very important....And, lastly, other things, like infrastructure and education spending, are important. This isn't all about austerity versus no austerity. Countries that are successful in dealing with these crises, such as Sweden, sometimes take them as an opportunity to change. We haven't."
Reinhart Testimony
before Senate Budget Committee, February
9, 2010. "In light of the likelihood of continued weak consumption in
the U.S. and Europe, rapid withdrawal of stimulus could easily tilt the economy
back into recession. To be sure, this is not the time to exit. It is, however,
the time to lay out a credible plan for a future exit."
In Praise of Carmen
Reinhart, Guardian,
April 2, 2010 (editorial page)
"The world's best known female economist has warned cutting the deficit the Tory way would send the UK back into recession."
"The world's best known female economist has warned cutting the deficit the Tory way would send the UK back into recession."
5 Myths about the
European debt crisis, by Carmen Reinhart and Vincent Reinhart, Washington Post, May 9, 2010
Myth #3: Fiscal austerity will solve Europe's debt difficulties.
"But fiscal austerity usually doesn't pay off quickly. A large and sudden contraction in government spending is almost sure to shrink economic activity as well. This means tax collections fall and unemployment and welfare benefits rise, undermining efforts to reduce the deficit. Even if new borrowing is reduced or eliminated, it takes time to whittle down a large debt, and international investors are notoriously impatient."
Myth #3: Fiscal austerity will solve Europe's debt difficulties.
"But fiscal austerity usually doesn't pay off quickly. A large and sudden contraction in government spending is almost sure to shrink economic activity as well. This means tax collections fall and unemployment and welfare benefits rise, undermining efforts to reduce the deficit. Even if new borrowing is reduced or eliminated, it takes time to whittle down a large debt, and international investors are notoriously impatient."
"One of the main goals of financial repression is
to keep nominal interest rates lower than would otherwise prevail. This effect,
other things being equal, reduces governments' interest expenses for a given
stock of debt and contributes to deficit reduction. However, when
financial repression produces negative real interest rates and reduces or
liquidates existing debts, it is a transfer from creditors (savers) to
borrowers and, in some cases, governments."
IMF Calls for Action on Eurozone, BBC Newshour,
July 19, 2011 (interview with Kenneth Rogoff)
"The current strategy that calls for years of austerity and
recession in the periphery countries is just not tenable."
The Euro's Pig-Headed
Masters (Kenneth Rogoff, Project Syndicate,
June 2011) "Instead of restructuring the
manifestly unsustainable debt burdens of Portugal, Ireland, and Greece (the
PIGs), politicians and policymakers are pushing for ever-larger bailout
packages with ever-less realistic austerity conditions."
The Economy and the Candidates, Wall Street
Journal Report with Maria Bartiromo, October 21, 2012 (interview with Kenneth
Rogoff)
Min 2:40 on Fiscal Cliff "Hopefully we won't commit economic suicide by actually putting in all that tightening so quickly." I like to see something like Simpson Bowles....If we did, we could have our cake and eat it too, we could have more revenue without hurting growth."
Min 2:40 on Fiscal Cliff "Hopefully we won't commit economic suicide by actually putting in all that tightening so quickly." I like to see something like Simpson Bowles....If we did, we could have our cake and eat it too, we could have more revenue without hurting growth."
Kenneth Rogoff on
Economy, European Debt Crisis, Bloomberg
Surveillance, July 27, 2012, Interviewer Tom Keene: "You told me five years and change ago that we would need four
trillion dollars of stimulus to get through this" min
7:55: "yes to great infrastructure projects, but not to just digging
ditches"
The Bullets Yet to Be
Fired, Financial Times, August 8, 2011 (by
Kenneth Rogoff)
"In the case of Europe, this involves very large debt write downs in the smaller periphery countries, combined with a German guarantee of central government debt in the rest....In the case of the US, policymakers need to offer schemes to write down underwater mortgages....there is still the option of trying to achieve some modest deleveraging through moderate inflation of say 4 to 6 per cent for several years.....Last but not least, monetary and financial solutions must be buttressed by structural reforms...."
"In the case of Europe, this involves very large debt write downs in the smaller periphery countries, combined with a German guarantee of central government debt in the rest....In the case of the US, policymakers need to offer schemes to write down underwater mortgages....there is still the option of trying to achieve some modest deleveraging through moderate inflation of say 4 to 6 per cent for several years.....Last but not least, monetary and financial solutions must be buttressed by structural reforms...."
Farheed Zakaria, GPS
"Krugman calls for Space Aliens to Fix US Economy," August 12, 2011,
Ken Rogoff: "Infrastructure spending, if it
were well-spent, that's great. I'm all for that. I'd borrow for that,
assuming we're not paying Boston Big Dig kind of
prices for the infrastructure."
Interview with Charlie
Rose, Business Week, December
2012, CR: Does this economy need further
stimulus?KR: "Certainly, withdrawing it at
too rapid a rate in such a fragile economy makes no sense....We need to have
areas where we spend money, like infrastructure, education."
Inflation is Now the
Lesser Evil, Kenneth Rogoff, Project Syndicate, December 2008, "It is time for the world's major central banks to acknowledge that
a sudden burst of moderate inflation would be extremely helpful in unwinding
today's epic debt morass."
No comments:
Post a Comment