The Failure of
Democracy and the Rise of the Welfare State
Are political
regimes fated to decay and die away, as everything in nature is?
Back in the
eighteenth century, men in England, France, and the United States conceived of
a new type of regime that would prevent the tyranny of the absolutist
monarchies that reigned at the time. They put their hopes in a balance of power
between various institutions of government, and in the periodical recourse to
election to purge the system of excessive corruption and entrenched power. The
democratic form of government established on those principles would work
wonders for over two centuries.
But now, in its
third century of existence, it is producing dysfunctional and potentially self-destructive
forms of governance. The United States has been deadlocked in the monumental
issue of its budget deficit and entitlements, unable to cut spending or raise
taxes. Europe as a whole is no less fiscally bankrupt, and measures to restore
its public finances are throwing the continent into economic depression and
political upheaval.
This is not the
first test for democracies that, over the last 200 and some years, have
weathered countless political crises. Throughout that period, democracies were
able to mobilize so many resources, human and financial, that they won epochal
wars against other regimes and were emulated on all continents. Yet, the
diagnostic today is severe: with age, the democratic welfare state as we know
it suffers from morbid obesity, and while the remedy is not hard to
conceive—rebalancing the relationship between the public to private sector—it
seems impossible to administer.
The etiology of
the crisis points at the very design of the regime: the patient will not take
the cure, voting out any government trying to cut public spending. Foreign
donors who bail out bankrupt governments are often slapped in the face by the
citizens of those countries. The recent woes of Greece and Cyprus show how the
people can lack responsibility and gratitude.
Political
theorists of ancient Greece were ambivalent about democracy. The Greek elite
liked to rule its own affairs but, as a privileged minority in an expanding
society, it had much to lose if a populist tyrant were to leverage the power of
the masses. Accommodations were made with monarchy, hoping for a king powerful
enough to keep the mob in check, and wise enough to protect the propertied
classes.
These misgivings
carried through the ages, and the coalition of well-off merchants, clerks, and
landowners in Western Europe and the Americas, who unseated monarchs to have
another go at democracy, sheltered their privileges behind the rule of law.
They generally did not conceive of democracy as an exercise open to everyone,
but rather as the prerogative of a propertied class with stakes in the system.
The door was left open to the masses whose condition, no longer restricted by
birth, could be improved through work and chance. Improvement would bring them
into the franchise. Until then, their place was at the periphery of the polity.
Those restrictions
could not hold and, by the middle of the twentieth century, suffrage had been
opened to every adult. The marriage of democracy and mass politics was not a
seamless affair, and it is good to remember that leaders such as Mussolini,
Hitler, and Juan Peron were actually elected to office. But most democracies
were able to keep their people away from toxic demagogues by setting up the
largest state project ever conceived, other than communism, since the Great
Wall of China: collective welfare.
The Rise of the
Welfare State
Unlike communism,
welfare left space for the market. Like communism, it aimed to cut off
individuals from their kin-based or ethno-religious communities, binding them
to the dual institutions of state and the state-regulated market. Functions
that were traditionally performed by the extended family—care for the sick,
young, and elderly; primary and vocational education; job placement; capital
accumulation and transmission—were moved to the state and the market.
Welfare was to be
the social contract of democracies, and the people signed on because, at least
at the time, the transition improved standards of living. Welfare brought
stability to cities whose populations exceeded ten million inhabitants and to
countries whose populations were well into the hundreds of millions. But the
cost was phenomenal.
The economic
viability of the model depended on continuous growth of the private sector,
from which taxes would flow. When that was not enough—which would not be
long—the prospect of future taxes served as collateral for public borrowing.
GDP did grow, but spending and debt grew even faster: the average OECD ratios
to GDP are now around 50 percent for public expenditures and 80 percent for
public debt.
With growth
structurally slowing down in the most developed countries, appropriations have
become a zero-sum game between those who get and those who will have to pay.
Yet, familiarity with gigantic deficits—the combined public debt of OECD
countries exceeds 40 trillion dollars—gives confidence that the system still
has some give in it. Many have come to imagine the state as the custodian of an
infinite supply of money, and their democratic rights as a claim to financial
entitlements.
While the seminal
economist John Maynard Keynes has demonstrated that government spending is not
always a zero-sum game, it can be if it is not a remedy to a temporary crisis
of demand, but a way of life, as it has been in the Western world since the
1970s. And it is not just money, but also the interference of the state to
favor a select few. Subsidies, scarcity-creating regulations, intellectual
property rights: there are hundreds of ways to game the market. While some
regulation is legitimate and necessary, in some sectors, from healthcare to
education, the business model is entirely dependent on the state-sanctioned
restriction of competition. The irony here is that democracy has returned to
the impasse from which it was born: the tyranny of corruption.
Democracy never
meant for elected officials to micro-govern, a task for a technocratic elite,
shielded from the pressure of special interests, with a holistic view on the
long-term commonwealth—the modern version of the Ancient Greeks’ philosopher
king. Elected officials were tasked with other functions, such as keeping the
technocracy nimble and accountable for producing results efficiently.
Crucially, officials had to “sell” to the people policies designed
technocratically (not democratically), mustering the kind of legitimacy that
brings together a country around a common purpose.
This distribution
of duties served as a buffer against populism and kleptocracy. In the United
States, this agent of governance, the Supreme Court, has time and again
dampened the excesses of overreaching government. In the European Union, the
Council has forced national governments to limit their deficit to 3 percent of
GDP per annum. Such institutional constraints allow officials to go to their
constituents absolved from responsibility for unpopular but necessary measures.
The Failures of
Democracy
Democratically
elected officials are failing to meet their end of the bargain. Respect for
democratic institutions—parliaments, heads of governments, and presidents
alike—has plummeted along with voter turnout. The re-elections of George Bush
in 2004 and Barack Obama in 2012, which should have settled the matter of their
leadership, did nothing to silence their detractors and mend the tears in the
American polity.
In the Middle
East, the revolutions of 2011 were as inspiring as the emergent democratic
regimes were unimpressive. Elected Islamist governments were received with such
skepticism by their people that they have been unable to govern. An explanation
for disillusionment is that democracy has dug itself into a hole by sourcing
legitimacy from a delivery of welfare that has been exposed as unsustainable.
Performance is disappointing, and can hardly improve given that the system has
also broken down at the level of micro-governance. The technocratic sphere of
competence is not sheltered enough by the political sphere, not autonomous
enough from the people, to produce meaningful reform. It is also morbidly
bloated, with the rigidity of senescence. In many countries, the primary
function of civil service is to obfuscate unemployment, an endemic scourge
correlated to the lack of dynamism of the private sector.
Biology has a
concept to describe the endless evolutionary race between an organized system
and the environment around it: the Red Queen Principle, from Lewis Carroll’s
character who states that “it takes all the running you can do, to stay in the
same place.” The Red Queen Principle applies, for instance, to the relationship
between complex living organisms (like humans) and the pathogens that
continuously seek to invade and leech from them. Faced with fast mutating
viruses and bacteria, the immune system has to rush to scramble its codes each
generation to stay ahead.
The same
phenomenon applies to the relationship between complex social organizations
(like a state) and the special interests and popular fancies that seek to take
advantage of them. Societies have changed considerably since the late
eighteenth century, and the democratic form of governance has perhaps not
changed enough. In the United States, lobbying epitomizes undue interference in
the policy process.
But instant mass
communication through 24/7 media and social networks also allows people to
mobilize in real time and oppose any unpleasant but necessary reform. Elected
officials are exposed to constant scrutiny, and technocrats are inhibited by
political meddling. With the rise of industry lobbies, trade unions,
professional associations, social networks, and militant groups, civil society
has evolved at warp speed. Far from being the victory of the democratic
principle, in the form of a check on the power of the state, the vibrancy of
civil society is an unprincipled usurpation which dooms those who fail to
mobilize.
States have had
bouts of over-indebtedness since the beginning of recorded history, and the
recourse is always the same: a mix of inflation, default (bankruptcy), and
confiscatory taxation—that is, a vast financial transfer to the state imposed
on the holders of state liabilities. However painful the reset, life will go
on, although not always for the regime. Quite a few tax hikes have triggered
revolutions—including the American and the French ones, which started the
modern democratic experiment.
If bad financial
management is the hallmark of tyranny, the mission of the democratic state is
to produce governance where the public would not abuse the private, where
future generations would not be sacrificed to the present. There are many ways
in which modern democratic states overreach; economy and long term planning are
not among them.
No comments:
Post a Comment