Why the Fed Can't Stop
Fueling The Shadow Bank Kiting Machine
Fractional reserve banking is unlike most
other businesses. It's not just because its product is money. It's because banks can
manufacture their product out of thin air. Traditional commercial banks
essentially create money through a well understood and time honored pyramiding
of loans. Depositors who understand that their deposits are thereby placed at
risk choose their banks accordingly.
Under
the bygone rules of free market capitalism, only one thing kept banks from creating
an infinite amount of money, and that was fear of failure. Failure
occurs when depositors come to believe that their bank has lent out too much
manufactured money to too many dodgy borrowers and may not be able to cover
depositors’ withdrawals. When this happens, depositors rush to reclaim their
money while there is still some left, leading to the bank’s collapse.
Under free market capitalism, banks compete along a spectrum of risk and
reward.Conservative
banks offer a higher degree of safety by maintaining larger reserves, thereby
manufacturing and lending out less money. Through word and deed they let
depositors know that they lend to only the most creditworthy borrowers, who
generally must post valuable collateral. These banks remain profitable because
they successfully attract prudent depositors willing to accept lower rates of
interest.
Banks of a more speculative bent offer a lower degree of safety,
maintaining smaller reserves to create and lend out more money. Seeking higher
returns, they often lend to less creditworthy borrowers who may put up poor
quality collateral or none at all. These
banks attract risk-taking depositors looking for a higher rate of interest. They
can be very profitable during periods of economic expansion but often fall into
distress during economic downturns.
Periodic bank failures remind depositors of the connection between risk
and reward. When
caveat emptor rules, smart depositors who pay attention make money and dumb
depositors who don't lose theirs.
Because the latter outcome is intolerable in a democracy, we have government-provided deposit
insurance and other taxpayer-financed backstops that shield most depositors
from the risk of loss. In theory banks pay premiums to fund this insurance. In
practice these premiums are not risk-based. Banks are not penalized for making
riskier loans, in turn often leaving the premiums too low to finance payouts. This creates a huge moral hazard,
as it frees depositors to seek the highest return without regard for safety.
Worse, it removes conservative banks’ competitive advantage. Under a government-guaranteed deposit
insurance regime, conservative bankers who want to stay in business must take
on more risk in order to pay the higher interest rates necessary to attract
depositors. This often sets off a race to the bottom, which results in periodic
banking crises.
After
each of these crises, politicians
promise taxpayers that it will never happen again. And each
time it does, the government creates a new set of labyrinthine regulations that
attempt to mimic the business judgment of conservative bankers. Minimum reserve
requirements are established, which normally become the maximum as there is
little advantage in exceeding them. And both depositors and the bankers
themselves become complacent about the banks’ investments because it is so easy
to privatize gains and socialize losses.
Banks
also learn that competitive
advantage can be obtained by either gaming the regulations or having cronies
write them. As regulations get more intrusive and complex,
politicians discover that they can be used to advance social policies, such as
increasing home ownership among voters with poor credit, thereby increasing the
risk on banks’ loan books.
This mixed economic system is the one that replaced free market
capitalism in hopes that it would prevent bank failures. Despite, and some even say because of, a
regulatory regime that discouraged conservative banking and rewarded reckless
mortgage lending, the banking system crashed - again - in 2007-2008.
What is not widely appreciated is that the ensuing government bailouts
allowed an underlying shadow banking system to not only survive but grow even
larger. It
is called the shadow banking system because it operates outside most
government-regulated banking laws. This is primarily because regulations and
accounting standards haven’t caught up with the practices of these banks, which
are relatively new and poorly understood.
It was
the seizing up of the commercial paper and repo markets that funds the shadow
banking system that abruptly halted the flow of liquidity that kept the
mortgage bubble propped up. This revealed
the underlying insolvency of Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and many commercial banks stuffed
with subprime mortgage securities accumulated under the mixed economic system
described above.
Powered
by an exclusive club
of primary reserve dealers, a group that once included high
flyers like Lehman Brothers, MF Global, and Countrywide Securities, these
shadow banks work hand in glove with the Federal Reserve to manufacture money
by pyramiding loans atop the base money deposits held in their Federal Reserve
accounts.
To the frustration of Keynesians, and despite an unprecedented
Quantitative Easing (QE) by the Federal Reserve, conventional commercial banks have broken
with custom and have amassed almost $2 trillion in excess reserves they are
reluctant to lend as they scramble to digest all the bad loans still on their
books. So most of the money manufactured today is actually
being created by the shadow banks. But shadow banks do not generally make
commercial loans. Rather, they use the money they manufacture to fund
proprietary trading operations in repos and derivatives.
Where does the pyramiding come from if shadow banks aren’t making loans
that get redeposited to fuel the cycle? Securities held as collateral by
counterparties in a repo contract can be rehypothecated by the lender to obtain
additional loans. (So can securities held in customer accounts, unless their
brokerage agreements expressly prohibit it. This was an unwelcome discovery by
MF Global’s hapless clients, who saw their assets whooshed off to London where
different brokerage rules allow such hypothecation.) Loans made against
securities held as collateral can then be used to either buy more securities,
which can be fed back into the repo market, or trade a bewildering array of
complex synthetic derivatives.
If this sounds like circular check kiting that’s because it is,
especially when you add in the issuance of commercial paper required to grease
the wheels. The
biggest difference is that an embezzler kiting checks does not have the support
of a central bank providing steady injections of liquidity, beefing up balance
sheets that create confidence in their debt instruments.
How much of the original high quality collateral must shadow banks hold
in reserve should some of their derivatives implode, as many did during the
last crisis? Zero. By repeatedly spinning the wheel, the top 25 U.S. banks have piled
up over $200 trillion in leveraged bets atop a thinning wedge of collateral,
claims to which are spread across an opaque and complex chain of counterparties
residing in multiple legal jurisdictions. These collateral claims are
co-mingled with an estimated $400 trillion to $1.3 quadrillion in notional
outstanding derivatives made by other banks around the world, altogether
amounting to more than 20 times global GDP.
Due to
the fact that accounting standards have not kept up with these innovative
practices, banks are
not required to report the gross notional value of the outstanding derivative
contracts on their books, only their net asset positions. These
theoretical Value at Risk positions, which would only be netted out if all the
contracts were unwound in an orderly manner—as one might unwind a check kiting
scheme before getting caught—can only be realized in a liquidity crisis if the
counterparty chains across which these contracts are hedged hold up.
These counterparty chains froze in spectacular fashion during the last
financial crisis. After the collapse of Lehman Brothers and with the insolvency of
AIG looming, a chorus of politicians, bankers, and bureaucrats browbeat the
government into delivering a system-wide bailout. As a result, many reckless
banks and bankers that should have been driven out of the market are back doing
business as usual.
The
largest banks learned that they need not worry about the possibility of
bankruptcy. When the next crisis hits, all they have to do is shout “systemic
collapse” and another bailout will appear. Being Too Big To Fail, they can maximize profits without
having to hold reserves against the risk of counterparty failure, knowing
that the taxpayer will always be there to make them whole.
The solution is not more regulations, which will never keep up with the
financial wizards whose lobbyists end up writing these rules anyway. In
addition, trades can be made anywhere in the world, so to be effective the
regulations would have to be global. As long as governments continue to prop up
failing banks, regulation will always be inadequate to mitigate the moral
hazard that accompanies bailouts. And, ironically, the added costs of
regulatory compliance will make it harder still for smaller and more prudent
banks to compete.
True to
form, Congress has not
solved the TBTF problem but has actually made it worse, loading
ever more regulations on commercial banks through Dodd-Frank. Meanwhile,
taxpayer exposure to the banking system has grown even larger.
Optimists believe that as long as everyone remains calm and keeps
believing everything is fine, then everything will be. Central planning advocates hope that the
kiting scheme can be unwound by extending banking regulations to cover the
shadow banks while the Fed somehow weans them off of Quantitative Easing.
Cynics believe that asking Washington to get the situation under control is a
hopeless quest, especially since few Congressmen have a clue what is really
going on.
Meanwhile
uncertainty hangs over the system since
bankruptcy laws, which differ from country to country, have not kept up with hyper-hypothecation. Moreover, the government’s handling
of the auto bailout shows that investors cannot rely on existing bankruptcy law
even when it speaks clearly on an issue. Therefore, no one really knows who
will have first dibs on the collateral when the music stops. And just what are
those high quality assets? Sovereign bonds and mortgage CDOs, which are
themselves subject to precipitous losses.
As the
debate drags on and global economic conditions worsen, the growing pyramid is being kept afloat
by the easy money policies of central banks too frightened to withdraw their
support lest a stock market correction trigger a cascade
of margin calls that brings down the whole system—much like last time.
All this money creation has not yet generated much visible consumer
price inflation. This is
partly because official inflation measures are
suspect but mostly because the bulk of the new money being created is
flowing into financial assets and not the consumer economy. This has inflated
asset bubbles to levels impossible to justify based on underlying economic
conditions, in particular the stock market where investors have fled in search
of yield. No one knows
when the bubble will pop, but when it does a donnybrook is going to break out
over that thin wedge of collateral whose ownership is spread across
counterparties around the world, each looking for relief
from their own judges, politicians, bureaucrats, and taxpayers.
When
that happens and the clamor for regulation, nationalization, confiscation, and
demonization arises there is only one thing we can be sure of. The disaster will once again be blamed on
a free market capitalism that has not existed in this country for over 100
years.
No comments:
Post a Comment