The greatest social thinker of the twentieth century
“The body of economic knowledge is an essential element in the structure of human civilization; it is the foundation upon which modern industrialism and all the moral, intellectual, technological, and therapeutical achievements of the last centuries have been built. It rests with men whether they will make the proper use of the rich treasure with which this knowledge provides them or whether they will leave it unused. But if they fail to take the best advantage of it and disregard its teachings and warnings, they will not annul economics; they will stamp out society and the human race.”- Human Action
By Art Carden
Had he not passed away at the tender age of 92 in 1973, Ludwig von Mises
would have turned 131 years old today. In my humble opinion, he was the
greatest social thinker of the twentieth century. In a series of breakthrough
contributions like The Theory of Money and Credit, Socialism: An Economic And Sociological Analysis, Human Action (his magnum
opus), and Theory and History–to
say nothing of a series of smaller and no-less-insightful works like Bureaucracy and Omnipotent Government–Mises
developed theories of economic growth and business cycles that are relevant
today. One of the wonders of the modern world is that his major contributions
are available to be perused or downloaded from the institute bearing
his name or from the Liberty Fund. Today, anyone
with access to an internet connection can access his works with little or no
trouble. Anyone with a USB drive can carry his greatest works on a keychain.
The progress that made this possible wasn’t an accident, and it wasn’t
random. Indeed, this brings us to Mises’s greatest contribution: his
demonstration that socialism cannot function as a rational economic system and
that private ownership of the means of production is necessary if value is
going to be maximized and waste is going to be minimized in the production
process.
Mises started–and in my humble opinion, ended–the debate over whether an
economic system based on common or social ownership of the means of production
could function with his essay “Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth.” He demonstrated
that it was impossible to know whether a particular production process was wise
(resource-optimizing) or unwise (resource-wasting) in the absence of prices for
the means of production. His socialist critics accepted this, and Oskar Lange
suggested that a statue of Mises be given a place of honor by the socialist
Central Planning Board (here is Murray Rothbard with more).
Mises carried his argument step further, though: he argued that these
prices cannot emerge without exchange, and exchange in turn cannot happen
without private ownership of the means of production. Many economists laud the
market for its efficiency properties as free markets generally direct resources
to their highest-valued ends while minimizing costs of production. In the
Misesian tradition, however, the market plays a much more essential role. It is
not merely one of a number of possible allocative mechanisms. Exchange in a
free market is an information- and knowledge-generating process. To adapt the
title of one of Hayek’s essays, competition in the free market is “a discovery procedure.” This
emphasis on the coordinating and knowledge-generating properties of exchange in
a free market with secure private property rights is one of the distinctive
features of the modern Misesian tradition, which is discussed in a three-part
series by my occasional co-author Steven Horwitz (1,2, 3).
Mises’s arguments, and the arguments of those who have followed him, do not
merely undermine arguments for pure, global socialism. They also undermine
arguments for interventionism more generally. Economists take a lot of heat for
focusing on market exchange and material prosperity, and it is fashionable in
some circles to say that “there is more to life than economic efficiency” as if
that decides an argument in favor of intervention. Not so: people respond to
incentives, even when you don’t want them to, and the knowledge-destroying and
incentive-distorting effects of interventionism all too often bring with them
unintended consequences that not only reduce economic efficiency but also harm
precisely the intended beneficiaries of the intervention.
It is for this reason that I urge my students to consider the consequences
of different interventionist schemes–to count the cost, as it were. In his introduction to
the new edition of Socialism from Laissez-Faire Books, Peter J. Boettke
makes an important point:
“Critics of economics say that economists know the price of everything but the value of nothing. Nothing, perhaps, is so dangerous intellectually in the policy sciences as an economist who knows only economics, except, I would add, a moral philosopher who knows no economics at all.”
Ludwig von Mises can no longer teach us economics in person. His astounding
intellectual contributions live on, though, in his writings and in the passion
for truth that shines through almost every word. Unfortunately, the people who
most need to read Mises probably won’t. In this light, I can close with nothing
better than the sober warning Mises offers in the last few sentences of Human Action:
“The body of economic knowledge is an essential element in the structure of human civilization; it is the foundation upon which modern industrialism and all the moral, intellectual, technological, and therapeutical achievements of the last centuries have been built. It rests with men whether they will make the proper use of the rich treasure with which this knowledge provides them or whether they will leave it unused. But if they fail to take the best advantage of it and disregard its teachings and warnings, they will not annul economics; they will stamp out society and the human race.”
No comments:
Post a Comment