Without growth, Europe is heading for a train wreck
by Frank Hollenbeck
Reading the financial press, one gets
the impression there are only two sides to the austerity debate: pro-austerity
and anti-austerity. In reality, we have three forms of austerity. There is the
Keynesian-Krugman-Robert Reich form which promotes more government spending and
higher taxes. There is the Angela Merkel form of less government spending and
higher taxes, and there is the Austrian form of less spending and lower taxes.
Of the three forms of austerity, only the third increases the size of the
private sector relative to the public sector, frees up resources for private
investment, and has actual evidence of success in boosting growth.
Let’s take a closer look at the Merkel
form of austerity being implemented in Europe in which governments “plan” to
cut their spending and raise tax revenues. Of course, “planned” cuts are not
actual cuts. Four years after the crash of 2008, the UK government had only
implemented 6 percent of planned cuts in spending and only 12 percent of
planned cuts in benefits. In almost all European countries, government spending
is higher today than it was in 2008. A new study by Constantin Gurdgiev of
Trinity College in Dublin examined government spending as a percentage of GDP
in 2012 compared with the average level of pre-recession spending (2003–2007).
Only Germany, Malta, and Sweden had actually cut spending.
Although several governments have raised
tax rates, tax revenues have collapsed in response. The large and growing black
markets in Greece, Italy, Spain, and even France are a testament to wrongheaded
European tax policies. Current commitments to reign in tax fraud are a joke
when tax rates are already at nosebleed levels.
Notably, the Merkel form of austerity
has led to an increase,
not a decrease, in the relative size of the public sector. For example, the
Greek public sector, while getting smaller, has nonetheless been contracting at
a slower rate than the private sector. Since the first bailout, Greece lost at
least 500,000 private sector jobs but shed far fewer public sector jobs. For
years, the Greek government has been pledging to cut 500,000 public sector
jobs, and in recent months, the Greek government has finally pledged to begin
laying off public sector workers over the next two years. A total of 12,500
civil servants, including teachers and police, face reassignment or the axe by
the end of the year, with a further 15,000 facing the same options next year.
Not only is this too little, too late, but it is also only a pledge.
The Keynesian form of austerity is no
better. According to these economists, we need even more government spending to
boost demand to obtain growth. For the Keynesians, the lavish amounts of money
already spent was apparently too little and not spent in the right places, yet
the last five years are a testament to the failure of this type of austerity.
We are now left with a massive debt overhang and little growth to show for it.
Government spending has simply “crowded out” private spending.
Ignored is the fact that we don’t need
government to boost demand because there is never a deficiency of demand.
Governments instead should be more concerned with the ability of the private
sector to produce the right supply.
Growth will come from the private
sector, and the austerity we need is one that makes the private sector larger
than the public sector and one similar to that implemented in 1920 in
the United States. In what Thomas Woods calls “The Forgotten Depression of
1920,” the U.S. government cut spending 50 percent and sharply reduced taxes.
The public debt was reduced by a third, while monetary policy was kept on hold.
The economy recovered quickly (in 18 months) and by 1923 the unemployment rate
had fallen below 3 percent.
A more recent example of similar tactics
is Latvia which followed a similar strategy in 2009-2010. It cut government spending
from 44 percent of GDP to 36 percent. It fired 30 percent of the civil
servants, closed half the state agencies, and reduced the average public salary
by 26 percent in one year. Government ministers took personal wage cuts of 35
percent, although pensions and social benefits were barely reduced and the flat
tax on personal income was left untouched at 25 percent.
The Latvian economy dropped 24 percent
in two years, but rebounded sharply in 2011 and 2012 with yearly real growth of
over 5 percent. Unemployment hit 20.7 percent in 2010, but has steadily
declined to a little over 12 percent today. Because the cuts prompted
deregulation, Latvia enjoyed a boom in the creation of new enterprises in 2011.
It was able to transition from a bloated construction sector to a vibrant
economy of many small- and medium-sized enterprises.
Latvia borrowed heavily from the IMF,
and was criticized in 2009 for its overly aggressive economic strategy. Latvia
recently repaid its loan to the IMF three years early, indirectly silencing its
critics.
Austerity worked because it was the
right form of austerity: one which gave people hope and one with a light at the
end of the tunnel. Today, Europe has austerity fatigue. It missed the
opportunity to implement the right type of policies.
Since it now seems impossible to
implement the right form of austerity, what should Europe do? To get back on
the path to growth, Europe needs to dump policies to spur aggregate demand, and
focus on policies which bring the right products at the right prices. As J.B.
Say said:
The encouragement of mere consumption is no benefit to commerce, for the
difficulty lies in supplying the means, not in stimulating the desire of
consumption; and we have seen that production alone, furnishes those means.
Thus, it is the aim of Good Government to stimulate production, of bad
Government to encourage consumption.
Without growth, Europe is heading for a
train wreck since it will shortly be unable to finance its debt. It must
refocus its strategy toward stimulating production, freeing up Europe’s
entrepreneurial spirit. This is a policy much more likely
to succeed.
No comments:
Post a Comment