Land policy in India is a bigger deal than sectarian politics in Syria
By WALTER RUSSELL MEAD
The world’s eyes are riveted on Syria this week, as the United States,
France and perhaps a few others organize plans to punish a bloodstained
government for its use of chemical weapons against its own people. It’s a story
that has everything: the prospect of violence, the political agony of an
embattled White House, David Cameron’s loss of grip, and perplexing questions
about right and wrong. For liberal internationalists, few international laws
are more important than those that ban the use of WMD against civilians; on the
other hand, when the political patrons of a war criminal block action at the UN
Security Council, liberal internationalists must choose between their highest
values and their most cherished institution.
That’s why the Syria story is dominating
the news this week, and like the rest of the world, VM has been following it closely. But another story that is getting less
attention is much more important for the future of the world: the economic crisis in India represents a much more
fateful moment in world politics than anything happening in Syria.
What’s so important about India’s economic
problems? It’s more what they tell us about the state of the country than the
severity of the problems themselves. The stock market jitters, the currency
crash, the GDP slowdown and the government deficit aren’t enough in themselves
to sink India. All economies go through rough patches every now and then, but
the question isn’t about a downturn. The question is whether the Indian
political system has what it takes to get the economy back on track.
Two horrible things happened in India this
week: an inept government reeling from serial corruption scandals and mounting
evidence of economic failure pushed two bad bills towards enactment. There’s a
wasteful “food security law” that will do much more to nourish India’s rich world
of government corruption than to help the poor on a sustainable basis, and a
poorly designed “land reform” law that could be even more crippling.
We’ve noted the food bill before;
the land law is new and its consequences could be devastating enough to India’s
growth prospects to change the course of world history. In India, under a law
dating from the British Raj, the government has wide powers of eminent domain.
Essentially, the government is the nation’s real estate agent, organizing
transactions between buyers (often Indian or foreign companies who want to
build factories, or Indian government organizations wanting to build roads or
other infrastructure) and the farmers and others who own the land. For many
Indians, this approach makes sense for two reasons. First, there are so many
small plots in India that without the convenience of government organization
(and its powers of eminent domain to force unwilling holdouts to sell), it
would difficult if not impossible for private organizations to get the land for
big projects. The second reason is that given the low level of education among
many rural people in India and their lack of economic sophistication, there is
a fear that unscrupulous investors will swindle the poor unless the government
is there to protect them.
This isn’t just paternalism. Rural life in
India isn’t always beautiful, and corrupt local officials, landlords and others
can and often do squeeze the poor unmercifully. It’s not at all clear that a
“free market” in land would lead to anything but the forced dispossession of
hundreds of thousands and even millions of poor farmers and their families.
But there’s a catch. The paternalistic
state, theoretically devoted to the welfare of poor farmers, is staffed by very
human and often very venal officials. Business interests wanting to develop
land can bribe politicians and officials to get the government to force land
sales; a system established to protect the poor is easily perverted into the
instrument of their destruction.
As a result, the business of land sales
for economic development in India often degenerates into an unholy mess. NGOs,
farmer organizations, corrupt officials, desperate farmers, families with
conflicting claims and many other parties get caught up in struggles that can
go on for years. Sometimes violent rebel groups get involved in land
controversies, and even in their absence these battles can turn violent as
farmers fight desperately to hold onto the only security they know. What makes
these struggles even more bitter at times is the knowledge on the farmers’ part
that the bureaucrats aren’t giving them the full and fair price for the land.
Like their counterparts in China, Indian officials and politicians see the gap
between the price paid by investors and the price paid to farmers as a revenue
source that both supports local government and in some cases lines the pockets
of local officials.
India certainly needs land reform, but as an editorial in the Hindustan
Times notes, this bill makes things worse. The
government’s land bill
envisages payment of twice the market rate for land in urban areas and
four times the market rate for land in rural areas — enough to make any
project, public or private, economically unviable. Then, it calls for the
consent of 80% of landowners before any acquisition can proceed.
The Times goes on to spell out the consequences:
the law mandates a windfall bonanza for landowners, requires social impact
studies that will drag out the process of land acquisition for “years if not
decades” and will make the acquisition of large plots of land for development
uneconomic all across India.
The problems don’t stop there. The Times concisely describes why the final
passage of this law would be a disaster of the first magnitude:
This provision could well spell the end of India’s dreams of emerging as
a manufacturing superpower. The only way to quickly lift what the western media
pejoratively refers to as India’s teeming millions into the lower middle
classes and then progressively higher, is to create industrial jobs.
The farm sector accounts for 16% of GDP but supports 60% of the
population. This is clearly unsustainable. We need rapid industrialisation. And
for this, we need land — not land that has been acquired from their owners for
a pittance and given to industry cheap, but land that has acquired at a fair
value and given to industry at a price that keeps projects viable.
We couldn’t have put that better
ourselves. India can only hope to provide a better way of life for its hundreds
of millions of poor rural people by rapidly developing as an industrial power.
To do that, private investors have to be able to buy land, and the government
has to be able to acquire land for roads, electricity plants and transmission
lines and all the other necessities of an industrial society.
Land blockages and infrastructure problems
have so far blocked India from benefiting fully from the globalization of
industrial production and landed the country in a Catch-22 style development
trap. Because there is no massive industrialization, most of the jobs and other
benefits of Indian globalization go to the well educated—the techies in the
cyberparks and the fluent English language speakers in the call centers. These
are the types of international businesses that can flourish in a country filled
with talented people but lacking the basic infrastructure that can support a
modern manufacturing economy.
But because the benefits of globalization
are so thinly spread, many in India resist further changes. In China, whatever
that country’s political problems, massive numbers of ordinary people know that
their jobs in manufacturing or in servicing companies that manufacture for
export are linked to China’s integration into the global trading system. While
China is in many respects a dangerously unequal economy, its global opening has
at least created opportunities for people in all walks of life. That is much
less true in India, so dangerous laws like this one have more support.
India must move towards an industrial
revolution; tens of millions, hundreds of millions of Indians must move from
the countryside to the city, from agriculture into manufacturing and services.
That is never easy, even under ideal circumstances, and India will be
attempting to accomplish this transformation as Indian labor faces tough
competition from China, other developing countries— and automation. There is no
time to lose, but India at the moment seems stuck.
This isn’t just an Indian story. Whether
or not India moves forward toward a modernizing economy is partly a story about
Indian incomes and social conditions; it is also a story about world
geopolitics. If India hesitates on the threshold of industrialization while
China moves swiftly ahead, the balance of power in Asia will become shakier
year by year. If India can keep pace with China, it is likely that Asian
geopolitics will settle down over time. With two economic superpowers rising
together, and a strong Japan on the scene, the Asian balance of power looks
reasonably stable. With one superpower rising and another potential superpower
on the sidelines, the picture could change.
In the long run, what India does about its
industrial and land use policy matters much more to the world than anything
that happens in Syria. It matters more to the happiness and economic security
of billions of human beings, and it matters more to the prospects for world
peace.
Even in the middle of yet another crisis
in the unhappy Middle East, Americans need to keep their eyes on the countries
in which humanity’s fate in the 21st century will be hammered out. Land policy
in India is a bigger deal than sectarian politics in Syria; we need to keep our
eyes on the big picture.
No comments:
Post a Comment