Defunding
or repealing the law is practically impossible, but here’s how we can fix it
by Richard
A. Epstein
It is now
common knowledge that the bugs in the Obamacare website have been embedded in
the system from the start. For the past two weeks, not only have many
individuals found it impossible to access the website, but they are often
frozen in place once they pass through the initial portal. The problems will
just get worse. The current law requires extensive communications between
enrollees and their chosen insurance carriers, as well as
massive interaction with both federal and state organizations. As a result, web
traffic builds up behind bottlenecks and leads to massive frustration. As I
warned last May, watching Obamacare unravel is a
painful business.
The Bright
Side of Bad News
Health and
Human Services Secretary Kathleen Sebelius has tried
to put a positive gloss on the messy situation with the dubious observation
that the system glitches are due to heavy consumer demand. Her statement subtly
implies that the nation’s alleged need for the program is the cause of its
momentary glitches. She claims that things are “getting better by the day.” Not
so. The government site was not built for heavy traffic, nor was it tested
before going live. It is no mean feat to try to fix a balky computer system on
the fly.
As a
result of these problems, calls to delay the implementation of the individual
mandate are now reaching a fever pitch, such as Peggy Noonan’s to delay the
individual mandate a year. The bugs need to be worked out before ordinary
people are slapped with fines for failing to enroll in the derelict system
before the penalty deadline now set for March 31, 2014.
Thus far,
the Obama Administration has been mum on the sources and extent of the
difficulties. But make no mistake about it: they reflect the broader structural
weaknesses of the program, which were hidden from view by the disastrous
launch. Nonetheless, the system’s basic design is flawed, and its gaffes will
become only more apparent as implementation moves forward.
Republicans
are howling to repeal and defund Obamacare. As a policy matter, that is surely
the correct move. But as a political matter, the prompt repeal of Obamacare is
just not going to happen over the uncompromising opposition of a Democratic
president and a Democratic Senate. So, if the first-best solution is not
possible, more modest fixes for Obamacare are in order until Republicans start
winning elections. Here are three areas of the law to change: the employer
mandate for employees who work 30-hours-per-week; the coverage rules; and the
medical loss ratio.
Part-Time
Employment
As of
January 1, 2014, Obamacare’s employer mandate kicks in with respect to
employees who work thirty or more hours per week for a single employer. Just
finding out who falls on which side of that line is no easy task. Much
employment is seasonable, which could make it difficult to classify individual
employees on one side of the line or the other without a close examination of
their working history, which then has to be updated on a periodic basis.
But the
larger difficulty is structural. As Andrew Puzder recently
argued in the Wall Street Journal, the closer we come to implementation of the
employer mandate, the stronger the pressure becomes for employers to hire
part-timers who unambiguously work less than 30 hours per week. It will not
happen in all cases. But in some significant fraction of cases it will be
cheaper for a firm to hire more workers on a part-time base than fewer workers
on a full time basis.
Alternatively,
some employers will find it more efficient to hire fewer high-skilled workers
with overtime payments in order to minimize the mandate’s burden. Both of these
Obamacare-driven strategies are inefficient because neither would be adopted in
a tax-free world, with higher optimal output.
The
administration wanted to keep the hours exemption low in order reduce the
number of employers who would avoid the mandate. What they did instead was to
put the cart before the horse. In the effort to force-feed the healthcare
market, they managed to cast a major pall over a struggling labor market. It is
far better to expand labor markets in ways that create more wealth instead of
restricting them for the sake of a botched employer mandate.
Obamacare’s
Coverage Rules
A second
major problem with Obamacare is how it sets healthcare rates in individual
markets. The administration’s insistence that these be called “exchanges” or
“markets” belies their coercive and confused nature. An open exchange is one
that allows companies that meet certain minimum standards of probity and
financial responsibility to sell their goods or services on terms and
conditions that they choose to offer: think eBay. But none of that is tolerated
on the Obamacare exchanges, as all parties are rigorously scripted to the kinds
of services they can offer and the prices that they can charge.
In this
case, the first problem is that the set of minimum benefits under the various
plans is defined so generously that people will have to pay for services that
they would never chose to acquire in a voluntary market. The clear implication
is that the higher coverage generates social losses, not social gains. The
inclusion of exotic items (e.g. habilitative care) not only raises the price of
access, but it also makes it harder to get sensible benchmark pricing in what
was, until the advent of the ACA, a non-existent market. Cutting back on these
benefits should go a long way to controlling some of the price issues that have
surfaced with the initial quotes, and bring healthcare costs in to greater
alignment.
Under the
current system, too many people make a beeline for coverage in the hopes of
receiving huge subsidies—subsidies large enough to lure them away from private
plans for which they pay market rates. That migration undermines private
insurance companies that currently serve these people. It also requires
cross-subsidies from healthier individuals to pick up the slack built into the
system. The required revenues will not come from direct government payments,
but only from other plan participants, namely younger enrollees now forced to
pay above-market rates to supply the subsidy—if they chose to participate,
which they often won’t.
This form
of community rating has pronounced effects. Under the ACA, the maximum allowable
rate differential is three-fold between a young person and a senior, but the
market differential is about five-fold. Under those circumstances, the young
person is likely to resist even movie-star exhortations to enroll
in a plan that offers a net negative.
That
tendency will increase because of the generous accommodations Obamacare makes
for applicants with preexisting conditions. Most insurance plans design their
enrollment and premium strategies to combat the constant risk of adverse
selection. People have private information about their healthcare status, and
thus are more likely to purchase healthcare at standard group rates when aware
of their own precarious healthcare position.
Most
traditional plans use various devices to control the risk of adverse selection.
These include an individual disclosure, which allows firms to raise prices or
exclude customers. With group plans, it is commonplace to require a minimum
level of employee participation to prevent individual opportunism. But
Obamacare goes in the exact opposite direction and requires insurers to enroll
parties who know of their increased risk.
There is
today a huge public ground swell that
insists that no one should be excluded from healthcare on the grounds of their
preexisting conditions. Nothing in the short run can stop that dynamic. But it
is at least possible to slow down its effects. Thus, if open enrollment is
allowed at any time, at least require all persons who enroll to remain in the
plan for a year so that the insurer can earn back some of the money that it
loses thanks to these strategic enrollments.
There is a
limit to the size and quantity of subsidies that can be required. Pushing the
balance back may well make access to the exchanges a more attractive
proposition for those who right now are likely to stay out. Even if some
community rating system is sacrosanct, its size is not. Tapering down on the
program is a sensible mid-level strategy. The blunt truth is that the
Republicans have to win elections in order to force a fundamental overhaul.
The
Medical Loss Ratio
Ascurrently
constituted, the ACA imposes extensive restrictions on the way in which
insurance companies spend their premium dollars. In an ordinary business
environment, the savvy firm is always making trade-offs at the margin between
its medical and administrative expenses. Finding the right combination lets
firms compete effectively in the marketplace. There is, moreover, no single
ratio that works for all firms: much depends on the composition of its insured,
the nature of its specialization, the local regulatory environment, and many
other factors.
The medical loss ratio pays scant
attention to these differences and limits the amount of “administrative
expenses” that can be spent to 20 percent of individual plans and 15 percent of
small group plans. Since 2012, firms that do not meet their respective targets
have been required to issue rebates to their
customers.
This
boneheaded system is yet another example of how Obamacare forces private
insurance companies to incur costly administrative expenses in order to deliver
inferior services to their customers. This system is based on the peculiar
belief that government agencies know, in the abstract, which expenses count as
administrative, and how much they can be. It also assumes that governments
should force firms into predetermined paths even though businesses, facing
competitive pressures, have a far better grasp of how their cost structures
should operate. These requirements are a back-handed form of price regulation,
which should and could be eliminated right now without gutting the core of
Obamacare.
Getting from Here to There
Repealing
Obamacare should be a high priority for the Republicans if they can win
national elections. But they can only get there if they play the short-term
game well. The usual three imperatives for healthcare are to ensure access and
quality while controlling price. I know of no top-down administrative system
that can begin to reach those three goals. The efforts to force access and
mandate quality are not only counterproductive, but they will also drive up
prices in ways that undermine both access and quality.
The only
viable counterstrategy treats deregulation as the first line of attack on the
inefficiencies of the current system. Reduce costs and avoid regulatory
nightmares, and access to care will rise as rates decline and quality of care
improves. Once this is done, targeting subsidies at certain individuals to
allow them to purchase healthcare plans that the market offers, such as the Healthy Indiana plan, without taking
over management of the system, will result in greater access without
compromising quality.
Playing
hardball is a losing strategy. The Republicans will never get their turn unless
they use today’s computer glitches and enrollment delays as a platform on which
to propose modest market-enhancing reforms. This might give the public the
confidence in the GOP’s ability to work on more substantial reforms down the
road.
No comments:
Post a Comment