The weak economic recovery in
the U.S. and the even weaker performance in much of Europe have renewed calls
for ending budget austerity and returning to larger fiscal deficits. Curiously,
this plea for more fiscal expansion fails to offer any proof that Organization
for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries that chose more
budget stimulus have performed better than those that opted for more austerity.
Similarly, in the American context, no evidence is offered that past U.S.
budget deficits (averaging 9% of GDP between 2009 and 2011) helped to promote
the economic recovery.
Two interesting European cases are Germany and Sweden, each of which moved toward rough budget balance between 2009 and 2011 while sustaining comparatively strong growth—the average growth rate per year of real GDP for 2010 and 2011 was 3.6% for Germany and 4.9% for Sweden. If austerity is so terrible, how come these two countries have done so well?
The OECD countries
most clearly in or near renewed recession—Greece, Portugal, Italy, Spain and
perhaps Ireland and the Netherlands—are among those with relatively large
fiscal deficits. The median of fiscal deficits for these six countries for 2010
and 2011 was 7.9% of GDP. Of course, part of this pattern reflects a positive
effect of weak economic growth on deficits, rather than the reverse. But there
is nothing in the overall OECD data since 2009 that supports the Keynesian view
that fiscal expansion has promoted economic growth.
For the U.S., my view is that the large fiscal deficits had a moderately
positive effect on GDP growth in 2009, but this effect faded quickly and most
likely became negative for 2011 and 2012. Yet many Keynesian economists look at
the weak U.S. recovery and conclude that the problem was that the government
lacked sufficient commitment to fiscal expansion; it should have been even
larger and pursued over an extended period.
This viewpoint is
dangerously unstable. Every time heightened fiscal deficits fail to produce
desirable outcomes, the policy advice is to choose still larger deficits. If,
as I believe to be true, fiscal deficits have only a short-run expansionary
impact on growth and then become negative, the results from following this
policy advice are persistently low economic growth and an exploding ratio of
public debt to GDP.
The last
conclusion is not just academic, because it fits with the behavior of Japan
over the past two decades. Once a comparatively low public-debt nation, Japan
apparently bought the Keynesian message many years ago. The consequence for
today is a ratio of government debt to GDP around 210%—the largest in the
world.
This vast fiscal
expansion didn't avoid two decades of sluggish GDP growth, which averaged less
than 1% per year from 1991 to 2011. No doubt, a committed Keynesian would say
that Japanese growth would have been even lower without the extraordinary
fiscal stimulus—but a little evidence would be nice.
Despite the lack
of evidence, it is remarkable how much allegiance the Keynesian approach
receives from policy makers and economists. I think it's because the Keynesian
model addresses important macroeconomic policy issues and is pedagogically
beautiful, no doubt reflecting the genius of Keynes. The basic model—government
steps in to spend when others won't—can be presented readily to one's mother,
who is then likely to buy the conclusions.
Keynes worshipers' faith in this model has actually
been strengthened by the Great Recession and the associated financial crisis.
Yet the empirical support for all this is astonishingly thin. The Keynesian
model asks one to turn economic common sense on its head in many ways. For
instance, more saving is bad because of the resultant drop in consumer demand,
and higher productivity is bad because the increased supply of goods tends to
lower the price level, thereby raising the real value of debt. Meanwhile, transfer
payments that subsidize unemployment are supposed to lower unemployment, and
more government spending is good even if it goes to wasteful projects.
Looking forward,
there is a lot to say on economic grounds for strengthening fiscal austerity in
OECD countries. From a political perspective, however, the movement toward
austerity may be difficult to sustain in some countries, notably in France and
Greece where leftists and other anti-austerity groups just won elections.
Consequently,
there is likely to be increasing diversity across countries in fiscal policies,
and this divergence will likely make it increasingly hard to sustain the euro
as a common currency. On the plus side, the differing policies will provide
better data to analyze the economic consequences of austerity.
No comments:
Post a Comment