Seventeen years ago, Bernard
Connolly foretold the misery that awaited the European Union. Given that he was
an instrumental figure in the EU bureaucracy and publicly expressed his doubts
in a book called "The Rotten Heart of Europe," he was promptly fired.
Mr. Connolly takes no pleasure now in having seen his prediction come true. And
he takes no comfort in the view, prevalent in many quarters, that the EU has
passed through the worst of its crisis and is on the cusp of revival.
The European political class, he says, believes that the crisis "hit
its high point" last summer, "because that was when there was an
imminent danger, from their point of view, that their wonderful dream would
disappear." But from the perspective "of real live people, and
families and firms and economies," he says, the situation "is just
getting worse and worse." Last week, the EU reported that the euro-zone
economy shrank by 0.9% in the fourth quarter of 2012. For the full year, gross
domestic product fell 0.5% in the euro zone.
Two immediate solutions present themselves, Mr. Connolly says, neither
appetizing. Either Germany pays "something like 10% of German GDP a year,
every year, forever" to the crisis-hit countries to keep them in the euro.
Or the economy gets so bad in Greece or Spain or elsewhere that voters finally
say, " 'Well, we'll chuck the whole lot of you out.' Now, that's not a
very pleasant prospect." He's thinking specifically, in the chuck-'em-out
scenario, about the rise of neo-fascists like the Golden Dawn faction in
Greece.
Mr. Connolly isn't just any Cassandra. When he predicted disaster, he was
running the European Commission's Monetary Affairs Committee, the Brussels
bureaucracy charged with ushering the euro into being. His public confession of
fear that the monetary union would inevitably produce an economic crisis not
only cost him his job, he says, it also cost him his pension, and he was barred
from his office even before his dismissal was official. In the introduction to
the paperback edition of "The Rotten Heart of Europe," Mr. Connolly
describes how his photograph was posted at entrances to the commission's
offices, as if he were a wanted criminal.
Mr. Connolly went on to a career as a private economist. His research notes
while at American
International Group's trading division
showed the same flair for bold prognostication. In 2003, as then-Federal
Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan cut interest rates to an unprecedented 1%, Mr. Connolly described the
U.S. economy as a debt-driven Ponzi scheme and predicted that interest rates
would have to fall even further in the next cycle to keep the scheme going.
Today Mr. Connolly provides his research notes to clients who presumably
pay a great deal for his thoughts. He generally doesn't talk to the press. And
he doesn't make public pronouncements or market calls, lest he
"agitate" his clients.
But with his book back in print, Mr. Connolly agreed to sit down in his
publisher's office to explain why the euro went wrong, why nothing has been
fixed, and what he expects to happen next.
Superficially, there is some basis for the official view that the worst of
the crisis is over: Interest-rate spreads, current-account deficits and budget
deficits are down. Greece's departure from the single currency no longer seems
imminent.
Yet unemployment is close to 27% in Spain and Greece. The euro-zone economy
shrank ever-faster throughout 2012. And—most important in Mr. Connolly's
view—the economic fundamentals in France are getting worse. This week France
announced it would miss its deficit-reduction target for the year because of
dimming growth prospects.
It's one thing to bail out Greece or Ireland, Mr. Connolly says, but
"if the Germans at some point think, 'We're going to have to bail out
France, and on an ongoing, perpetual basis,' will they do it? I don't know. But
that's the question that has to be answered."
The official view is that the bailouts of Greece, Ireland and Portugal—and
maybe soon Spain—are aberrations, and that once those countries get their
budgets on track, their economies will follow and the bad patch will be a
memory. Mr. Connolly calls this "propaganda."
And here we get to the heart of Mr. Connolly's rotten-heart argument
against the single currency: The cause of the crisis, according to the
"propaganda," he says, was "fiscal indiscipline in countries
like Greece and financial-sector indiscipline in countries like Ireland."
As a consequence, "the response is focused on budgetary rules, budgetary
bailouts and rules for the financial sector, with the prospect, perhaps, of
financial bailouts through the banking union, although that remains
unclear."
But even if the Greeks were undisciplined, he says, "both the
sovereign-debt crisis and the banking crisis are symptoms, not causes. And the
underlying problem has been that there was a massive bubble generated in the
world as a whole by monetary policy—but particularly in the euro zone" by
European Central Bank policy.
The bubble formed like this: When countries such as Ireland, Greece and
Spain joined the euro, their interest rates immediately dropped to near-German
levels, in some cases from double-digit territory. "The optimism created
by these countries' suddenly finding that they could have low interest rates
without their currencies collapsing, which had been their previous experience,
led people to think that there was a genuine rate-of-return revolution going
on," he says.
There had been an increase in the rates of return in Ireland "and to
some extent in Spain" in the run-up to euro membership, thanks to
structural reforms in those countries in the pre-euro period. But by the time
the euro rolled around, money was flowing into these countries out of all
proportion to the opportunities available.
"And what kept the stuff flowing in," Mr. Connolly says,
"was essentially the belief, 'Well, yes, there is a high rate of return in
construction.' " That in turn depended on "ongoing expectations"
about house appreciation "that were in some ways not dissimilar to what
was happening to the United States in the middle of the last decade. But it was
much bigger."
How much bigger? "If you scale housing starts by population, then the
housing boom in Spain and Ireland was something like three or four times as
intense as the peak of the boom in the U.S. That's mind boggling."
That torrent of money drove up wages far faster than productivity improved,
while cheap borrowing led to major deficit spending. After the 2008 financial
panic, the bubble inevitably burst.
So what's needed now is not simply a fiscal retrenchment, or even a
retrenchment along with banking reform. Wages and prices have to adjust to
something like their pre-bubble trends, Mr. Connolly says, to make these
economies competitive again. One way to accomplish that would be a massive
depreciation of the euro—"really massive."
If that's not feasible, he says, Europe can try to "recreate the
bubble" by bringing back the conditions that allowed Spain to borrow so
cheaply. That is "essentially what [Mario] Draghi"—the European
Central Bank president—"appears to be trying to do: to recreate a
bubble." Mr. Draghi, by threatening to intervene in the sovereign debt
markets, has driven interest rates in Spain down substantially. But because the
banking system is distressed, and because house prices continue to fall, even
these lower rates are not driving investment into the country the way they did
before. And even if Mr. Draghi were to succeed, Mr. Connolly says, the ECB
president would merely be "recreating exactly the dangerous, unsustainable
situation that we had in the middle of the last decade."
Which leaves Europe with the last option: Germany pays. As Mr. Connolly
puts its: "You can say to a country like Spain: 'No need to adjust your
competitiveness, you don't need to have full-employment trade balance. You can
still have full-employment current-account balance because we will give you
transfers instead.' And by definition, if the point of that is to avoid
adjustment, you have to do it this year, the next year, the year after, and
every year, forever."
That is not how Brussels and Frankfurt see it. In their view, a little help
now will simply ease the transition back to a stable future, when the transfers
will cease. Of all the countries that have been bailed out so far, Ireland
comes closest to realizing this goal. But Ireland, Mr. Connolly notes, "is
a much more flexible and much more open economy than Spain, Greece, Portugal,
France, Italy." The less flexible economies have been slower to adjust,
with the consequence that wages, instead of dropping to a sustainable
post-bubble level, remain high—resulting in mass unemployment.
Which brings us back to the politics of the euro crisis. At some point, the
people in the affected countries presumably will call a halt to the pain and
sweep in a government willing to think the impossible—leaving the euro, for
example.
To avoid that, Germany could
well agree to pay for a transfer union, either believing that the transfers
needn't be permanent, or hoping they'd be less expensive than a euro break up.
But, Mr. Connolly warns, once a mechanism is in place to transfer money from
Germany to the current-account deficit countries, it's only a matter of time
before Germany is faced with the question of adding France to its list of
dependents—something even Berlin may not be willing or able to afford.
German reunification has cost the former West Germany about 5% of GDP a
year, with no end in sight. The expense has proved politically tolerable, Mr.
Connolly says, because there was a strong sense that "they were reuniting
their country." But such solidarity does not exist within Europe.
"There is no European demos, and you're not going to create a demos by
setting up a system in which you say, 'We will give you money, you will follow
these rules,' " says Mr. Connolly. "It simply will not work."
No comments:
Post a Comment